Moved by Lord Bridges of Headley That this House takes note of the
Report from the Economic Affairs Committee Making an independent
Bank of England work better (1st Report, HL Paper 10). Lord Bridges
of Headley (Con) My Lords, it gives me great pleasure to open this
debate. I begin by thanking all members of the Economic Affairs
Committee for their time, toil and commitment which went into
producing our report, and our excellent clerk, our policy adviser,
and our...Request free trial
Moved by
of Headley
That this House takes note of the Report from the Economic
Affairs Committee Making an independent Bank of England work
better (1st Report, HL Paper 10).
of Headley (Con)
My Lords, it gives me great pleasure to open this debate. I begin
by thanking all members of the Economic Affairs Committee for
their time, toil and commitment which went into producing our
report, and our excellent clerk, our policy adviser, and our
special adviser Professor Rosa Lastra. I also remind the House of
my registered interest as an adviser to and shareholder in Banco
Santander.
Our report aimed to answer a simple question about the Bank of
England: how is independence working? We asked that partly
because last year marked a quarter of a century since the Bank
was granted operational independence over monetary policy—a
decision that signified an enormous transfer of power from
elected representatives to unelected officials. Since then, the
Bank's remit has grown. It has undertaken quantitative easing on
a massive scale and inflation hit a 41-year high in October 2022,
resulting in a loss of public confidence in Threadneedle Street.
All this raises questions about the Bank's accountability and
performance. Accountability and performance are different, but
clearly related. If an unaccountable body performs poorly, what
then? Our committee thought it was time to kick the tyres and
learn lessons. Our focus was primarily on monetary policy; we did
not examine individual decisions, nor events.
Let me start with the Bank's overall record on inflation; I
stress “overall”. Inflation remained within 1% of the MPC's
target almost 90% of the time between 1997 and 2021. The precise
contribution of independence to that record is difficult to
quantify—we heard that globalisation contributed too—but we
concluded that independence should be preserved for the simple
reason, to quote one witness,
“that there is a greater likelihood of interest rates being
adjusted for economic reasons, rather than to suit … political
objectives”.
That said, we concluded that reforms are needed and I will
highlight some of the reasons why.
The first is the Bank's recent performance on inflation. Like
many central banks, the Bank of England mistakenly thought that
inflation was transitory. Possible reasons for this include a
perceived lack of intellectual diversity in the Bank, as in other
central banks, which contributed to insufficient challenge to
modelling and forecasts. In particular, our committee was struck
by the notable absence of any detailed discussions about money
supply in the monetary policy reports. To quote one witness,
“money supply was ignored in a rather foolish fashion”.
The second reason we need reform is what has happened to the
Bank's remit, which, as I said, has ballooned. This complexity
risks jeopardising the Bank's ability to prioritise its primary
objectives. The governor told us:
“It makes policy-making more complicated”.
Its sprawling remit risks drawing the Bank into the Government's
wider policy agenda, raising questions about accountability,
which I will come on to.
Another reason we need reform is to address the blurring of
monetary and fiscal policy thanks to quantitative easing. A
powerful tool to combat the monetary contraction after the 2008
financial crisis, QE's continued deployment since then swelled
the Bank's balance sheet to a record high of just under 50% of
GDP and shortened the overall duration of the Government's
liabilities, increasing the vulnerability of the Government's
overall debt stock to movements in short-term rates.
Although the quantum of quantitative easing is a monetary policy
decision, decisions on debt duration have consequences for debt
management. Furthermore, and crucially, the taxpayer is on the
hook for any losses incurred by the Bank thanks to QE. But the
deed of indemnity—the contractual document between the Bank's
asset purchase facility and the Treasury—is secret. That all
needs addressing.
That brings me to another reason we need reform: accountability.
The growth in the Bank's remit and QE have not been met with a
commensurate increase in accountability and parliamentary
scrutiny. A democratic deficit has emerged which risks
undermining confidence in the Bank and its operational
independence.
Given those reasons, we proposed a number of what I consider to
be very reasonable steps to address all this. I shall not read
out a long laundry list, but they included: pruning the Bank's
remit; reviewing hiring and appointments; a memorandum of
understanding which clarifies how the interaction between
monetary policy and debt management should operate; publishing
the deed of indemnity; and a parliamentary review of the Bank's
remit and operations every five years. Our overarching point was
simple: the framework for independence and the operations of the
Bank need reform.
What was the response from the Bank and the Treasury? Let me
start with our concerns around forecasting and the big issue of
groupthink. As many Lords will know, the Court of the Bank of
England commissioned the Bernanke review into its forecasting.
That review, in itself, shows the benefit of challenge. The
review's findings were pretty scathing of the Bank's approach to
forecasting and recommended changes on which I am sure a number
of noble Lords will want to comment. But the review did not go
into any depth on the key issue of diversity of thought, for the
simple reason that it was not included in the review's remit. To
my mind, this is odd. As the governor himself told us, the models
are not like a “sausage machine”, in his words, but reflect
people's judgment. I agree with that; in fact, I would go
further: the output of models are not tablets of stone. They
might shape decisions, but they should not determine them. What
is more, the Bernanke review's tight remit specifically excluded
looking at any past decisions or events, so it was really not set
up to ask the basic question: what went wrong, and why?
What is being done to improve challenge and tackle groupthink? In
the responses, we are pointed to dissenting votes on the MPC.
This is obviously true, but it rather ignores the fact that,
between March 2020 and September 2021, when inflation was rising,
the MPC was, month after month, unanimous in its view that this
rise was transitory. Next, we are told that no review of Bank
appointments is necessary, as the Treasury is committed to
diversity in public services in its appointments. But what kind
of diversity? Is diversity reflected in the recent appointments
to the Bank's most senior positions? Might they suggest that the
Treasury is the primary school for the Bank?
We are told that the MPC monitors monetary aggregates, so our
recommendation, that there should be an analysis of their
relevance to the Bank's inflation outlook, was rejected. I am
conscious that we might fall into the trap of groupthink that
there is groupthink. However, having mulled over the evidence
that we received, I think that our recommendations are measured,
and that the response to them was—to be polite—somewhat
defensive.
What of the other reasonable proposals we made, that the remits
of the MPC and the FPC should be pruned? The Treasury's written
response states that:
“As both Committees have complex roles, it is right that their
remit reflects this complexity”.
But the next paragraph says that it agrees that there is benefit
in improving the clarity and focus of the remit letters—something
the Chancellor confirmed to us a few weeks ago, when he told our
committee that the Treasury “could probably do better” at
simplification. However, he then pointed out that, despite his
slimming down the remit as regards climate change, climate change
objectives
“are bedded into what the Bank of England has to do anyway”.
I find all this slightly confusing, so I have a simple question
for my noble friend the Minister: does the Treasury think that
the remits are still too complex? Are we at the beginning, not
the end, of the process of simplification?
Let me now turn to QE and QT. Both the Bank and the Treasury
argue that we do not need a memorandum of understanding to
clarify how the interaction between monetary policy and debt
management should operate. I beg to differ. The taxpayer is
ultimately bearing the risk of QE and the costs incurred, and
decisions are being taken concerning huge sums of public money
without regard to the usual value-for-money requirements—a
position that the Treasury Select Committee in the other place
concluded is “highly anomalous”. More clarity is needed.
That brings me to the need to publish the deed of indemnity. The
governor told us:
“I could not see anything in it … that I think would excite
people if it were published, but it is not my decision—it is the
Treasury's”.
Yet the Treasury's response says that the document should not be
published because it contains “market sensitivities” and
“operationally sensitive information relating to QE”,
which risks
“undermining the transparency of the APF”.
The Bank and the Treasury appear to be at odds on this. In my
simple mind, either this document will not excite people, or it
contains market-sensitive information which will. Can the
Minister tell us who is right—the Governor or the Chancellor? But
the bigger point is this: given that the taxpayer is bearing the
cost of QE, Parliament should surely be told how the relationship
between the Treasury and the Bank works and who is responsible
for taking what decisions and on what grounds.
That brings me to the final issue: parliamentary accountability.
Operational independence should mean just that: politicians stay
out of the Bank's day-to-day decisions. But how often does
Parliament debate the Bank's overall performance, its remit
letters or issues such as QE and QT? The answer is: not much. Our
focus here in Parliament is largely on fiscal policy, not
monetary policy—the Treasury in the City of Westminster, not the
Bank in the City of London. We need to address that democratic
deficit. An overarching review of the Bank's remit every five
years, as our committee recommended, would not undermine
independence but strengthen it. Such a review could look at one
of the other big issues: the inflation target itself, on which we
heard conflicting views as to whether 2% is the right target.
Another question a parliamentary review could consider is whether
we have the right balance between accountability and independence
with regard to the appointments of the most senior Bank officials
and their tenure and reappointment. As I said at the start, when
things go wrong, does Parliament really have sufficient means to
hold the Bank's leadership to account?
The Bank and the Treasury are staffed by many professional,
committed public servants. I certainly do not want to trash
either institution, but I fear that the tone of the Bank's and
the Treasury's responses to our report and its reasonable
recommendations reminded me of a policeman at the scene of a
crash. Concerned onlookers want to know what has happened and
why, but the policeman politely shuffles them off, saying,
“Nothing to see here. Just an unfortunate incident. Move along,
please”. Well, I am staying put. Yes, operational independence
should be preserved, but reforms are needed.
11.59am
(Lab)
My Lords, I am very grateful to the noble Lord, of Headley, for introducing
this debate, and for the exemplary work that he and other members
of the Economic Affairs Committee have done to produce this
report. I was privileged to be a member of the committee
previously, when it conducted inquiries into both quantitative
easing and the case for a central bank digital currency. This
report revisits those subjects, at the same time as taking a
broader view of the Bank's working. The result is a powerful
endorsement of Select Committees generally sticking with subjects
and themes over a longer period of time, rather than allowing an
inquiry to be seen as a one-off.
There is not a single conclusion or recommendation in this report
with which I disagree, which prompts me, like the noble Lord,
, to ask myself whether the
unanimity of the committee and the wide support for its findings
represent an example of the very groupthink that the committee
questioned the Bank of England and other witnesses on. So perhaps
I should express my disappointment that the title of the report
is blander than some in the past, even if the Governor of the
Bank of England was critical of the committee suggesting that the
Bank's use of QE might equate to “addiction”.
As a young banker—so a very long time ago—I developed admiration
and respect for the Bank and its culture. As a market
participant, it had a profound understanding of the financial
markets without generally being captured by them. Of course, even
in those halcyon days, there were problems and failings, from
BCCI to Barings, but there was widespread confidence in the
integrity and competence of the Bank, even though it did not
enjoy formally the independence that was granted to it by the
Labour Government in 1997.
The structure and remit of the Bank has, as the noble Lord,
, already said, changed
considerably—massively—even since then: from one deputy governor
to four and from eight executive directors to 21. The
multiplicity of additional objectives and “have regards to” was
also highlighted by the noble Lord. Has the culture of the Bank
remained fundamentally unchanged as a result of this process and
evolution? I believe that at the core, the best aspects of this
culture remain, but that the recommendations of the report are
important and necessary steps for protecting and reinforcing
it.
I will focus on two issues: transparency and governance. In doing
so I will comment on more specific policy issues and performance.
I profoundly believe that transparency should be at the heart of
public bodes generally; even the intelligence services are now
significantly more open, if in a limited and carefully controlled
way. Rather nostalgically, this made me think of my maiden
speech, a frightening 42 years ago, on the subject of a European
directive on bank accounting. Back then, although the clearing
banks did report their true profits, merchant banks still
disclosed profits only after transfer to or from a hidden
reserve. As a middle-rank employee of one such bank, I questioned
whether this really added to the stability of the financial
system, faced by innumerable chairmen of banks in the same
debate—I think the management of banks has become a little more
diverse—arguing for the maintenance of the status quo.
Transparency should be at the core of the financial markets, and
of the Bank of England's role in them. For that reason, I regret
that, in the otherwise sensible review of the Bank's forecasting,
Ben Bernanke did not advocate the adoption of forward guidance or
the use of a so-called dot plot to provide markets with more data
on which to base their interest rate expectations. The central
bank is not there to provide the framework for traders to
maximise the opportunity for trading games; it is there to create
a stable and predictable environment for the benefit of the
economy as a whole.
Likewise, as the noble Lord has already touched on, I am baffled
by the Treasury's refusal to publish in full the indemnity under
which the Bank of England makes whole any losses from the QE and
QT programme. The reasons given by the Government are as opaque
as the policy itself. In what way would the publication of the
deed of indemnity jeopardise the Government's cash management
operations? Would the Minister be kind enough to answer that when
she comes to wind up, and explain why the protection of the Debt
Management Office's operation is not unfairly at the expense of
other market participants?
After the nearly three years since the committee's report on QE
was published, it is still hard to come to any definitive
conclusions, but this latest report provides an important update.
I believe that the QE programme, in its three phases, was right
in principle but wrong in degree. Its efficacy in bringing
stability to the financial markets at times of maximum stress was
clear, but it was of indeterminate impact in more general
macroeconomic management. As a result, the scale of the purchases
was almost certainly too great, and the speed of subsequent sales
too slow. This has arguably exacerbated the problems of
responding to a rising interest rate environment, and increased
the cost to the Exchequer of the intervention. Can the Minister
say what the net realised gain or loss currently is since the
start of the programme, and what the mark to market unrealised
loss is on the assets still held by the Bank, all of which are
for the Treasury's account under the deed of indemnity, as -far
as we know?
Very briefly, on governance and appointments there are serious
doubts about, among other factors, intellectual diversity and
political independence in relation to the court, the MPC and
senior management. Some of this is visible; more lurks below the
surface. I very much hope that the next Government—no
complacency, on today of all days, but I hope a Labour one—will
conduct a thorough review of the governance arrangements and
appointment rules for every part of the Bank of England, and in
addition look at the whistleblowing and independent process for
resolving problems as and when they occur.
I very much hope that the Economic Affairs Committee will
continue to bring its laser-like focus on the workings of the
Bank of England, with many aspects of its operations not covered
in this report. As the noble Lord, , has also advocated, I hope
that your Lordships' House will have much more time than in the
past to debate these issues.
12.07pm
of Earl's Court (CB)
My Lords, I declare my interest as chairman of C Hoare & Co,
a bank that opposed the setting-up of the Bank of England, became
reconciled to it a couple of centuries ago, and now regards it as
a privilege to be regulated by the Bank.
I congratulate the noble Lord, , and members of the committee
on a first-rate report. Operationally independent institutions
can survive and prosper only if there is proper parliamentary
accountability. All too often, that accountability can descend
into cheap point-scoring. I believe this House's Economic Affairs
Committee plays a crucial role in injecting serious, rigorous and
impartial thought into economic policy debate.
Like the noble Lord, , I was a little disappointed
by the Government's response to the report. I should confess to
having drafted similar responses, with an appropriately dead
hand, in the past. I am hoping the Minister will be a little more
forthcoming in her response than the Chancellor was, but I am not
betting on it.
It is good news that inflation is firmly heading back towards the
Bank of England's target of 2%, but we should not underestimate
the impact of the recent rise in prices. Inflation is not some
technical economic construct; it has a pernicious effect on
people's lives. It affects their ability to budget and to plan.
It has the biggest impact on those least able to protect their
incomes, and that is usually the weakest and most marginal in
society.
It is therefore important that we learn the lessons of the
upsurge in inflation in 2021-22. The Bernanke report is a good
start but, as others have noted, his remit was quite narrow. The
Bank's forecasting model clearly has limitations, but then so do
all forecasting models. That is why we should never become
mesmerised by them.
Economic policymakers need to step back from mechanistic
forecasts and focus on the underlying data here and now.
Sometimes that data tells a clear story. Quantitative easing was
necessary in 2009 and it was effective, but later rounds of QE
were an imperfect response to what were, in any case, supply
shocks. Ever-increasing amounts of QE were necessary to have an
impact on long-term interest rates and, in my view, resulted in
an excessive build-up of money and liquidity in the system. QE
did not cause inflation, but it certainly enabled it to take
root.
I do not want to be too harsh on the Bank. As Bernanke observes,
other central banks made similar mistakes, and the build-up of
excess demand was as much the Treasury's responsibility, through
an excessively loose fiscal policy, as it was the Bank's, but I
hope the Bank will pay just a little more attention to monetary
and liquidity indicators in the future.
That brings me to my second point. The Bank is doing a good job
in unwinding QE, and it underlined its independence in pressing
on in the autumn of 2022, despite potential political pressure
from the Government. But, as QE unwinds, we are going to hear a
lot about the losses sustained by the Bank. We hear rather less
about the gains from the early years of QE, when interest rates
were falling. Of course, had the ring-fence that the late wisely put in place in
2009 remained there this would have been less of a problem, but
the coalition Government chose to, in effect, draw down the gains
as a way of meeting their fiscal rules. We are now paying the
price.
I anticipate that future Governments, faced with even more
challenging public finances, will want to put a stop to the
fiscal leakage caused by QE. The key thing here is that the
Government should not interfere in monetary policy: the
remuneration of reserves must be a matter for the Bank. In taking
any tax decisions, the Treasury needs to take into account the
impact on the efficiency of the banking system as a whole.
The committee's report is right to draw attention to the
ever-increasing breadth of the Bank's remit. It is always
tempting for the Government to leave it to independent
institutions to take the difficult decisions, but that carries
big reputational risks since it draws the Bank further into
debates best left to democratically elected politicians. It also
fails to recognise that the Bank has limited instruments at its
disposal. I fear the Government sometimes ignore Tinbergen's law
that you need as many policy instruments as you have independent
objectives.
The committee has also made some good points on appointments.
Noble Lords will not be surprised that I am more relaxed than
most about the Treasury's colonisation of senior policy positions
at the Bank, and I welcome the appointment of Clare Lombardelli
as a new deputy governor, who has experience working at the Bank
and the OECD as well as the Treasury, but I agree with the
committee that the Government need to find the right balance when
it comes to appointments. I would welcome more interchange with
the private sector.
I wonder whether we need quite so many deputy governors as we
have. I recall advertising for one vacancy and conducting a
process. The Chancellor ended up appointing two candidates,
simply because both were very well qualified and he and the then
governor could not decide who was the best.
Recent events have underlined the importance of external members
of the MPC. It has been good to see, on the one hand, Swati
Dhingra ploughing her lone furrow arguing for looser policy and,
on the other, Catherine Mann and Jonathan Haskel making the case
for tighter policy. I was struck by a recent report from an
external member of the MPC that mentioned staffing shortages
constraining external engagement. I wonder whether the Bank
executive should provide a liaison person at a more senior level
to ensure that the externals' needs are met. Independent thought
matters, and the Bank should continue to find ways of supporting
external MPC members.
Finally, I should briefly mention the vexed issue of the
publication of the deed of indemnity relating to the asset
purchase facility. This puts me in mind of the Schleswig-Holstein
question. There were probably three people who understood it:
, who is, very sadly, dead;
me, who cannot remember; and my noble friend Lord King, who, as
luck would have it, is not mad. Fortunately, he is the sanest man
I know. He is also a man to be reckoned with, not least because
yesterday he was appointed president of the MCC, on which I
congratulate him. That the committee—and, by implication, my
noble friend Lord King—has recommended that the deed be published
is good enough for me. I can conclude only that the reason the
Chancellor has not published the deed is that he did not
understand the question. I would therefore like to ask the
Minister under what, if any, circumstances the Government would
publish the deed of indemnity.
To come back to where I started, this is a good report by the
Economic Affairs Committee and I support its recommendations. The
guiding principles of monetary policy put in place in the 1990s,
not least by the noble Lord, , of an inflation target of 2%,
maximum transparency and an operationally independent central
bank still hold good. Bank independence works and Governments
interfere with it at their peril.
12.16pm
of Lerwick (Con)
My Lords, I congratulate the noble Lord, , on his excellent speech and
this very good report. I was not a member of the committee but I
am most impressed by the report and agree with all the
conclusions. I will concentrate on recommendations 10 to 13,
which deal with forecasting, the alleged lack of diversity, and
groupthink—subjects mentioned by the noble Lord, . I want also to look at the
Bernanke report, which we now have.
In discussing forecasting, it is important, as I think the noble
Lord, , suggested, to
demythologise the subject. First, contrary to what many people
believe, policy is not dependent on forecasts. Secondly, we do
not, and should not, elevate forecasters into some priestly caste
examining the entrails and telling us whether the gods will look
favourably on a particular action. The gods are often deaf.
Forecasting responds to a deep human need but, alas, the
forecasts are often wrong.
There are several reasons why forecasts are fallible. One, which
we should welcome, is that human beings are not machines or
computers. They do not always react as they did last time.
Another is the limits of government statistics. I do not think I
should be saying this, but do we really believe that we can add
up all activity in the economy month by month and measure changes
to the last month within a fraction of a percentage point?
Inevitably, government statistics are continually revised.
Recessions that once undermined confidence and spread doom
mysteriously disappear years later. Then there are exceptional
events. You cannot forecast a pandemic. You may know that one is
likely, but you do not know when. These are exceptional events
but, unfortunately, history is exceptional events.
In his response, Dr Bernanke made some constructive suggestions
for improving the Bank's forecasting capacity to do with staff,
software and hardware, but I suspect that these are all at the
margin. They will always be subject to the limitations inherent
in forecasting that the noble Lord, , referred to, and one
cannot escape the need for an element of judgment.
The governor, Mr Bailey, pointed out that the Bank has not one
model but several, but that invites the aphorism: all models fail
but some are useful. Dr Bernanke makes this very point: a
forecast can be inaccurate and still be useful in enabling us to
understand why the policy was wrong. Forecasts make a central
bank more transparent and accountable, particularly if a policy
has been consistently applied but the outcome is not as
forecast.
Dr Bernanke's comments on the Bank's forecasts are,
interestingly, somewhat milder than the newspaper headlines. He
points out that the Bank was in the middle of the pack of central
banks when it came to inflation and output. Its belief that
inflation was transitory was one shared by many central banks,
but that merely poses another important question: why did so many
central banks get it so wrong? Was it a case of groupthink?
Interestingly, Dr Bernanke defends the Bank of England against
accusations of a lack of diversity in the MPC. Surprisingly, his
view is that there is more diversity than in other central banks,
and some of the witnesses, including Charles Goodhart, agreed, so
it will be interesting to have the Minister's comments.
Too much diversity of thought for the sake of diversity itself
can push a committee towards artificial consensus in which no one
believes. This is where the fan charts, so loved by the Bank of
England, have been so convenient. Who can disagree with a fan
chart covering so many possible outcomes? As in an oriental
dance, a fan can be used to conceal as well as to reveal. For
that reason, Dr Bernanke recommends getting rid of the fan charts
and substituting conditional forecasts, which he terms
“scenarios”. This might help to deal with the problem of
exceptional events, but will it contribute at all to forward
guidance?
What about groupthink between central bankers themselves? There
may be value in forecasts that are wrong, but there is a
difference between predicting the right trajectory with errors
and predicting a completely wrong trajectory. Many central banks
thought the pandemic would continue to be deflationary, hence the
resort to a huge injection of quantitative easing. At the time, a
number of commentators, including Paul Tucker, the former deputy
governor of the Bank, questioned why central banks wanted to
stimulate aggregate demand just as aggregate supply was closing
down. It was almost as though there was an assumption that QE
ought to be the default response to every crisis. That would
surely be a mistake.
Dr Bernanke is a disciple of Milton Friedman. I was therefore
surprised that he did not address the point made in conclusion 11
of the report that the MPC did not seem to have had any detailed
discussions about the money supply or made any analysis of
monetary aggregates and their effect on inflation. To be fair,
the governor denied that this was the case, but Roger Bootle said
in his evidence:
“Over the past few years … we have gone from a situation in which
economic policy … was governed entirely according to … a certain
definition of the broad money supply”—
that was the policy in the early 1980s—
“to one in which, apparently, the Bank took no notice of monetary
aggregates at all”.
I was particularly interested in this, for the very reason that
the noble Lord, , kindly mentioned: in
1992, when we introduced a new framework for policy, namely
inflation targeting, the target was accompanied by target ranges
for monetary aggregates. The regime of inflation targeting was
continued and carried through to Bank of England independence by
, but the ranges for monetary
aggregates were discontinued. Inflation targeting is not a
perfect policy. It can be criticised for being backward-looking
and a rear-mirror policy. But monetary policy, as Dr Bernanke
reminds us, operates with time lags and therefore enables
policymakers to focus on not just the current rate of inflation
but what we expect inflation might be in two years' time.
The report makes the point that the Bank has too many secondary
objectives to which it is asked to have regard. Many of these
objectives are not really affected by the instruments available
to the Bank. This must be true of climate change. The Government
ought to be clear that tackling climate change is a matter for
the Government. To expect the Bank to lead on that makes no
sense. I quote the governor himself, who said that climate
change
“is not really an issue of monetary policy”.
In addition to the inflation target, the Bank is also charged
with supporting the Government's objectives on growth and
employment. A major change was introduced in 2013, when gave the Bank a new remit in
which the MPC was tasked with setting out the trade-off when
deciding how long it would be before an above-target inflation
rate came back to target. As the governor said, these changes
gave the Bank much more flexibility over how quickly it could
bring inflation back to target. This considerable latitude, which
is welcome in one sense, may be another reason why the Bank was
so slow to raise interest rates and get inflation back towards
target—and we are not there yet. As things have demonstrated in
the United States, the last furlong may still prove difficult.
Indeed, one former central banker said to me that, if we get
inflation back to target without positive real rates of interest,
it will be the first time this has ever happened. Let us hope
that the optimists are right and that we are heading back towards
target.
As my noble friend said, the Bank is very
different from the one made independent in 1997-98. It has
expanded its discretion and the tools it uses. Its credibility
matters. So it is important that it is robustly scrutinised and
challenged, precisely as this report and this debate are
doing.
12.25pm
(Non-Afl)
My Lords, I declare my interest as a member of the Court of
Directors of the Bank of England but speak today in a personal
capacity.
First, I offer my compliments to the noble Lord, of Headley, and his committee
for the thoroughness of their evidence sessions, attracting a
star cast of witnesses, to provide a timely review of the Bank's
25 years of operational independence. Together with the review of
economic forecasting commissioned by the court from Professor Ben
Bernanke, the Bank now has a substantial body of independent
input on which to propose forward-looking reforms. I know the
governor and his colleagues are taking this process seriously and
will provide a further update by the end of the year.
As someone who has experienced the Bank in close proximity for
the past 18 months, I am pleased to share some observations and
hope that I can dispel a few myths and add some nuance to this
debate. At the outset, it is worth noting that in my brief time
serving on the court, I have not come across anything remotely
resembling the deep state, but instead a group of truly committed
public servants who are faithfully seeking to fulfil their
statutory remits.
The Bank takes accountability to Parliament incredibly seriously
and devotes substantial time preparing for and participating in
evidence sessions. In fact, if anything, the scope for
improvement in scrutiny lies less with the Bank and more through
enhancing the capabilities, attitude and co-ordination within
Parliament. The decision to appoint separate committees of each
House to review post-Brexit financial regulation is a case in
point. If there is a democratic deficit of accountability, it is
often a self-inflicted one. With due respect to the House of
Commons, it should be especially mindful of the behavioural
consequences of seeking “gotcha” moments which might generate
media headlines but do little to gain deeper insight into the
trade-offs which often lie at the heart of key policy issues.
This makes our institutions more risk averse and contributes to a
culture which incentivises overregulation and suppresses
innovation.
The core conclusion of the report on the effectiveness of
independence is not only reassuring but a timely reminder of the
underlying rationale for removing political involvement from
day-to-day monetary policy decisions. During this election year,
we can be confident that, if and when interest rates start to
come down, they will do so for economic and not political
reasons.
The benefits of this policy credibility in anchoring expectations
should not be underestimated. It is often difficult to prove a
counterfactual or attribute cause and effect, but we saw the
disastrous consequences when market confidence evaporated in
autumn 2022. The emergence of the unfortunately named “moron
premium” in UK gilts is a proxy for the type of cost that
citizens would incur if political decision-making trumped
economic reality.
Among the other key conclusions of the report were concerns about
groupthink, mission creep and boundaries between fiscal and
monetary policy. I shall touch on each. The Bernanke review
demonstrated that the process of challenge is as much about the
analytical tools available as the individuals. The court meets
regularly with external members of the policy committees, who are
a diverse and engaged group. They contribute positively to
challenging the executive and each other, with little evidence of
groupthink, as demonstrated by the historic voting record of the
MPC. However, they require the necessary support and input. One
significant gap in recent years has been deciphering
post-pandemic changes in the labour market. That has probably
been more significant in our understanding of inflation than
monetary aggregates.
On the remit, the Bank is a rule taker, not a rule maker. The
post-financial-crisis structure of the Bank, determined by
Parliament and further embellished by the recent Financial
Services and Markets Act, is a complex web of committees and
mandates that hangs together and works largely as intended. In
turn, it shapes the organisational structure of the Bank, which
feels proportionate to the scale and responsibilities that it
holds, but it places an almost superhuman requirement on the
governor to be across a vast span of policy and organisation.
For the MPC specifically, given the limited policy instruments at
its disposal, it is not clear how adding multiple secondary
objectives achieves much more than a feelgood factor for
politicians. Streamlining the remit letters would be welcome but
remains a matter for the Chancellor of the day, subject of course
to scrutiny from Parliament. I concur with my colleague David
Roberts, chair of the court, that organisations work best when
they have clarity and simplicity of objectives and goals.
It is entirely appropriate for fiscal policy to be
asymmetric—namely, the MPC takes the Government's fiscal policy
as a given, and the onus is on the Chancellor to make
tax-and-spend decisions that do not undermine price stability. It
is right that this modus operandi is underpinned by close
dialogue between the Bank and the Treasury but not by explicit
co-ordination.
With regard to quantitative easing, I have sympathy with concerns
about swapping out longer-duration gilts with short-term
deposits. That makes the cost of servicing government debt more
volatile, but it is something that the Treasury was fully aware
of when it granted the deed of indemnity to the Bank to
facilitate QE. In the context of quantitative tightening, as long
as the Bank and the Debt Management Office are in appropriate
dialogue, which they are, a memorandum, as suggested, would add
very little.
The role of the court has evolved over time. It has modernised
into a unitary corporate board responsible for everything up to,
but not including, policy decisions. That includes resource
allocation and budgets, investments, culture, capabilities,
technology and delivery for a 5,000-strong organisation with an
£800 billion balance sheet, which processes a similar amount in
payments every day. The court is very much part of the
accountability chain, as acknowledged in the committee's report.
Our ability to shape the organisational agenda and provide
internal challenge is significant, and the current court is
certainly up for shouldering that responsibility, as demonstrated
by our commissioning of the Bernanke review.
However, there are limitations. Like a conventional private
sector board, we do not possess hire-and-fire powers over senior
management, unfettered rights to determine strategy, or absolute
oversight. At times this is frustrating, but it is equally
unrealistic to expect an elected Government to cede complete
control. Instead, we exercise our mandate through influence, with
much depending on the receptivity of the serving governor and
deputies to receive the court's input, as well as through
collaboration with the Treasury. To make the court more effective
and better use our expertise, I believe that closer involvement
in making appointments and in setting budgets, especially with
the introduction of the bank levy, would help to strengthen
overall governance and accountability.
The Bank is a unique organisation that plays a crucial role in
our nation's economic life. We should certainly seek to improve
its operations and hold it to proper account, something that I am
personally committed to as a member of the court, but equally we
shoot ourselves in the foot if we undermine the Bank's
credibility, standing and independence, which has largely served
us well over the past 25 years and more.
12.35pm
of Soho (CB)
My Lords, I too thank the committee for this extremely effective
and wide-ranging report. I shall make a short intervention with
three different hats on.
The first of those hats is as president of the British Chambers
of Commerce. We work closely with the Bank on our quarterly
economic survey, and our customer and policy insights team works
closely with it to swap and use data between the two
organisations. It will perhaps be no surprise to this Chamber
that, as I travel about as president of the BCC from Poole to
Coventry to Doncaster to Glasgow, I hear anxieties about two AIs:
artificial intelligence and alarming inflation. Our recent
quarterly economic survey shows that business confidence is still
very flat. Businesses do not invest at the minute and, although
there has been some easing in their hiring constrictions and they
are beginning to find more of the talent they need, confidence
levels are still low.
I know from conversations with businesses as I travel about,
whether to a cheese-wrapping factory or a racehorse training
college in Doncaster—one of my favourite days out—that part of
the reason for that is people's opaque view of what is happening
in the economy, at the heart of which we must put the Bank of
England. More can be done to explain the role of the Bank
and—this goes to my noble friend Lord Macpherson's point—how it
is affecting people further down the chain in the economy, who
often bear the brunt of the inflationary aspects that we see: a
small supplier having a horrible time with their supply chain, or
a business struggling to pay the wages it needs to hire people in
its bars. While we have a close and productive working
relationship with the Bank of England, we also see the direct
consequences of the policies that it enables. I personally
believe that more could be done to keep the transparency and the
levels of trust high in what the Bank of England is doing for the
economy, especially among the 85% of our economy that are small
businesses, as noble Lords will know.
The second hat that I wear is as a director of Peers for the
Planet, an organising group in your Lordships' House, as many
noble Lords know. While I hate ever to disagree with my far more
learned friend the noble Lord, , I believe it is a risk that
the Bank of England is not putting resources into climate change
analysis. Of course the Bank is not responsible for the policies
that will help us to combat the climate crisis but, even as
recently as 2022, we saw a German drought directly impact small
businesses because of issues related to our supply chains here
into the UK, and that created a small inflationary peak. It is
essential that we do not reduce the Bank's capacity to analyse
the effects of the climate crisis as they hit us. We know that
the Bank has substantially fewer climate-based resources than
other central banks of similar size and scale, and 54 experts
wrote to the governor in March this year to say so.
For my third point—because I can never resist an opportunity in
your Lordships' House to talk about digital transformation—I am
wearing the hat of an ex-digital champion for the UK and creator
of the Government Digital Service and GOV.UK. I realise it was
not in the remit of this committee's work, but I am much struck
by the extremely harsh assessment in the Bernanke report of the
Bank's IT and digital systems. There is plenty of talk about
collaboration with the fintech sector and I have seen the
governor talking about the impact of AI in the world, but that is
different from the investment needed in hardware and software to
have an effective Bank. We know that across the institutions in
this country there is a substantial deficit of understanding of
what the digital world is now enabling, and the tools that we
have in the modern age which will enable us to do a better
job.
I am clearly not an expert in the Bank of England but I
appreciate the scale and challenge that this would present to any
institution. I urge the Government to keep up the pressure,
advice and help in supporting the Bank to make those necessary
transformations. Catching up with digital investment is very
hard. It can be very expensive and can go very wrong, but it is
also essential.
The committee's report starts by saying that the Bank of England
was established in 1694 for the “public Good and Benefit” of all
people. I urge the Bank of England to make sure that it is still
using the tools of and looking at the risks of the modern age,
while thinking about the make-up of the economy for the modern
age to fulfil that remit.
12.40pm
of Chelsea (Con) (Maiden
Speech)
My Lords, I stand in this House to make my maiden speech, aware
of the great honour that membership of this House entails—surely
undeserved in my case. With each week that I am here, I get to
understand more of the extraordinary nature of this House, of the
wonderful and supportive help that is given to us Peers by the
doormen, the clerks and the many talented and experienced
officials. I am so grateful to the many who helped me be
introduced to this House: Garter, my noble friends and , noble Lords on
all sides of the House, my excellent mentor and noble friend
, the Clerk of the Parliaments,
Black Rod and many others.
I am told that it is customary to offer brief details of one's
life to noble Lords before commencing upon the body of one's
speech. Perusing other maiden speeches, I was glad to note that
at least a few noble Lords had chequered early lives, which is
something I share with them. But in my mid-20s, I managed to get
myself to America, first studying finance and economics at MIT
and then staying in the US for almost two decades, advising banks
around the country and on Wall Street, which gave me knowledge
and experience of relevance to this debate. Happily married in
New York, I had not planned to return to the UK but, in 1992, was
offered an opportunity to run a large British company that at
that point was on the verge of bankruptcy, which fortunately for
me meant that no one more competent than me had any interest in
taking it on. The company survived its encounter with me; I was
happy to be back in Britain. I later branched out into the field
of venture capital and have founded a score or more of new
companies, mostly of a scientific or technological nature—at
least some of which did not go bankrupt.
Moving on to my attempted contribution this afternoon, I heartily
recommend the excellent report of my noble friend Lord Bridges's
committee to this House. I had been warned not to say anything
controversial in a maiden speech; however, Ben Bernanke's report
has thoroughly beaten me to the punch on that. For my own effort
here, I offer noble Lords what I hope are three less
controversial conclusions that can be drawn from the report.
First, it is welcome that money is now to be taken into
consideration. We all know that inflation, as the noble Lord,
of Earl's Court, has just
said, is devastating—particularly for the old, the poor and those
living on fixed income. The cost of living rises for everyone.
For retiring savers who do not have a defined benefit pension
arrangement, buying annuities during a time of quantitative
easing means very low future lifetime incomes. Yet excessive QE
creates excess money, which then creates inflation, which then
destroys the small value of the retiring savers' income even
further. On the other hand, for borrowers, QE offers attractively
low initial interest rates—but that causes asset inflation, so
you have to borrow to the hilt to buy your house, and then
inflation arrives. Interest rates double, as do your now
unaffordable mortgage payments, so both savers and borrowers
suffer from QE. Is a QE-inflation-recession cycle a better option
than letting markets decide interest rates and letting economies
recover more naturally than with intervention?
Some would argue that the QE approach has proved worse, so it was
welcome that the Bank's governor stated in evidence that he
believes that money plays a part in inflation. The Bank of
England's chief economist, less reassuringly, stated that the
elevated level of UK inflation stems largely from the impact of
external shocks rather than excess money growth. Yet Tim Congdon,
with the moral advantage of having predicted the arrival of 10%
inflation, disagreed in his evidence. He said that the
“globalisation idea” is very wrong and that
“this three-equation new Keynesianism … is a catastrophic set of
ideas”.
The noble Lord, Lord King of Lothbury—I add my congratulations to
those of the House on his election yesterday as president of the
MCC—hit the nail on the head when he said in the evidence
sessions that we looked in vain for references for money and
lending in the reports of the Bank.Inflation did not happen
everywhere around the world: it happened neither in Switzerland
nor Japan, for example. The difference was in their monetary
policies, so it is good news that the Bank will pay greater
attention to money volumes. We look forward to hearing in further
detail on how it proposes to take account of money volumes in
future.
Secondly, the report offered valuable recommendations for
enhancing the Bank's risk management. The committee's report was
thoughtful and valuable. It asked the right questions and came to
good conclusions, which I hope will be implemented. The committee
called, as did my noble friend this morning, for diversity of
viewpoints so that more scenarios would be offered to the Bank.
It suggested that better fallback plans could be created. An
example would be creating a plan to deal with the risk that the
Bank had apparently identified some years earlier: that the
leveraged LDI funds would fall over. My noble friend of Aspley Guise had warned
the Bank about this back in 2017.
It is also arguable that the Bank might take into consideration
the dangers of oversharing information with the market: for
example, by communicating up front a hard end date to a
stabilisation programme, which in itself would destabilise the
markets. The Bank could also consider stepping forward to
communicate to the Government any concerns that were raised by
both the Bank and the committee in evidence regarding the
inherent risk that has been created by the Bank being required by
the Government to attend to what my noble friend called in the evidence
sessions the “rambling rose” of no fewer than 25
government-imposed “have regards”.
Finally, on the value of the Government and the Bank aligning and
co-ordinating better, most of us agree that the Bank of England
must be independent. But, as a former Chancellor pointed out
during evidence, it also has a further requirement, which is to
support the Government's economic policy. How to reconcile these
two requirements? It is easy when the Government and the Bank are
agreed on a proper economic approach, but more difficult when
they differ. That is a conundrum whose answer may lie in the Bank
not seeking to be too doctrinaire—for example, in deciding to
embark on an aggressive QT programme. If the Bank is opposed to a
Government's policy or thinks that its actions might upset that
policy, then arguably it should take great care to discuss with
that Government any honest and honourable differences in economic
viewpoint as soon as possible. In particular, it should consider
possible changes in its timing of any planned major announcement
which might otherwise accidentally coincide with any equally
major but opposing government announcement.
I am close to overrunning, so I bring my remarks to a close. I
thank your Lordships for their forbearance and attention. I hope
my words might have some impact in reinforcing some of the
poignant thrusts of the committee's report.
12.49pm
(Con)
My Lords, I think we just heard a flavour of why at least one
former Prime Minister was in the habit of publicly saying that my
noble friend was a far more reliable
forecaster than the Treasury. It is a great privilege and
pleasure to follow his maiden speech.
I hope I can say this as an ex-politician among other
ex-politicians: if you have been close to government, you can see
how far a politician can go by just saying the right things and
voting the right way but making barely a dent on the real world.
That option is not open to the entrepreneur. My noble friend has
gone through life making a tangible and benign difference in
field after field. Most obviously, in business he has turned
around hundreds of companies, perhaps most spectacularly the firm
PA. I speak not of the wire service, I should say in this place,
but of the technological and scientific consultancy, which was
effectively bankrupt when he took it over and which he left with
a valuation of $2.5 billion.
He has done the same thing as president of the Albert Hall. Look
at the outside next time you are there and see the transformation
made possible by the £11 million surplus that my noble friend
created as president. He did the same—I am conscious that I may
be queering his pitch with a great many of those in the Chamber
now—as the chairman of the committee of Vote Leave, taking over
with a deficit and leaving with a victorious outcome.
He is very hands-on. He has most recently been not just
purchasing and supplying ambulances for Ukraine but driving them
across the border himself in quite difficult conditions. As much
for his cheerful and infectious optimism as for his keen
intellect and focused pragmatism, we are very fortunate to have
him alongside us in this place.
We are living through an unprecedented and uncontrolled monetary
experiment. Starting in March 2009, the Bank of England began a
programme of money printing that would have put to shame a 1970s
Latin American junta. Since then we have increased the amount of
money in circulation by an almost unbelievable 50%. Nearly half
of that increase has been since 2020 as a consequence of the
pandemic.
You cannot magic up that amount of currency without deleterious
impacts on people's lives, although people do not always join the
dots. A number of the things that people complain about in this
country have their root cause in excessively loose monetary
policy—most obviously the squeeze on living standards, but also
the rise in house prices, the divergence between haves and
have-nots in terms of assets, and the public sector strikes that
continue to plague us, as noble Lords will know if they travel
here by train. They all have their roots in excessive
inflation.
We heard about the malign consequences of inflation from the
noble Lord, of Earl's Court. I think I
would go further than he did. He said that QE exacerbated but did
not cause inflation. What else will cause inflation if not such a
massive expansion of the money supply? Milton Friedman said that
inflation is always and everywhere a monetary phenomenon; it is
caused by too much money chasing too few goods—“Milton! thou
shouldst be living at this hour: the Bank of England hath need of
thee”.
It was quite extraordinary to hear Gertjan Vlieghe, then a member
of the Monetary Policy Committee, say in April 2020 that the
balance sheet of the Bank would be comparable to those of the
central banks of the Weimar Republic or Zimbabwe—his words, not
mine. How can we look at that and not consider the consequential
impact on people's lives in the real world?
I have little to add to the brilliant analyses of my noble
friends and , but let me make a point about
accountability. When people complain about rising prices, rising
asset values and the difficulties of having to run to stand
still, to whom should they direct their complaints if the root
causes are independent authorities, which have been put
deliberately beyond the reach of elected Ministers? If the vast
majority of the decisions that impact on our lives are taken not
just by the Bank of England but by a series of other quangos and
agencies, from the Climate Change Committee to the European Court
of Human Rights and the Office for Budget Responsibility, the act
of casting a ballot is devalued.
That is something that this report takes some steps towards
addressing. My noble friend hinted at this, but he could
have gone a little further. He talked about the mandates and
appointment processes for governors and other senior staff at the
Bank of England. If you are in for a couple of terms and then no
one will bother you again, that strikes me as a fairly weak form
of accountability.
I would also like to see Parliament taking some responsibility
for the mandate of the Bank. Specifically, I would like to see
its terms of reference tweaked so that this kind of unprecedented
monetary expansion cannot happen without approval. I would like
to see the terms of the Bank of England changed so that the
maintenance of the value of the currency, sound money, is
expressly recognised as one of its goals. Whether or not you
agree with me, and whether or not you think that is a
proportionate policy, surely we need stronger mechanisms of
oversight.
Today is local election day. It is one of the few elections that
your Lordships are allowed to participate in. The polls are still
open, but I will go out on a limb here and say that the election
result will be a massive win for the “Can't be bothered” party.
The number of people who took the trouble to register to vote but
did not bother to cast a ballot today will be greater than the
votes cast for all the other parties put together. Why is that?
Is it sheer cynicism or apathy? Is it not that the decisions that
most directly touch on people's lives have been lifted out of the
democratic process and placed in the hands of bodies that are
invulnerable to public opinion? Changing the mandate of the Bank
of England will not solve that problem on its own, but it is part
of a process of restoring the supremacy of the elected
representative and thereby restoring honour, meaning and purpose
to the act of casting a ballot.
12.57pm
(CB)
My Lords, I am also grateful to the noble Lord, , for introducing this debate.
I congratulate the noble Lord, of Chelsea, on his maiden
speech and his entrepreneurial career. I am sure we will hear
much more from him on many of the topics we are talking about
this afternoon.
This is an important report. The noble Lord, , set out its conclusions well.
In particular, he described how the monetary framework has been
severely tested in recent years. I was not a member of the
committee when the report was published, but I am pleased to say
that I am now once again a member of it.
It is striking. We must bear in mind that the increase in prices
over the past three years has been over 20%—more than three times
the target at the time. We should not forget that, on the eve of
the Russian invasion of Ukraine, inflation was already well above
target. It must also be acknowledged that this is a problem
shared with many other major countries, although it has been
pointed out that some managed to avoid this—certainly to the
extent that we have suffered.
I will limit my comments to some of the issues covered in the
report where I have some experience. The first relates to
economic forecasts. When the noble Lord, , introduced the inflation
target rating in 1992, we knew that maintaining inflation within
a narrow range would not be easy. Interest rates have to be set
on the prospects for inflation some time ahead. This inevitably
means some reliance on judgments about the outlook over the next
two years or even more.
I carry many bruises from my own time in the forecasting
business. The evidence is clear that making accurate forecasts
for inflation over this kind of time horizon is very difficult.
The noble Lord, Lord Lawson, often said to me when he was
Chancellor that forecasts work well when the economy is behaving
well and you do not need them, but they are at their weakest when
the economy is subject to volatile circumstances and you need
them the most. I think the experience since the Bank of England's
independence is consistent with this. During the great
moderation, as we know, the forecasting record was astonishingly
good. It is only when we have come to this time of turbulence
that we have seen just how bad it can be.
I remain an enthusiastic supporter of trying to create models of
economic processes. There is much to be learned from the
discipline of testing hypotheses about behaviour against data
from the past. But, if events take us outside our historic
experience, it has to be said that these relationships will be
prone to error. I fear the Covid lockdown was one such
experience. So, although I have some sympathy for the
forecasters, especially in a world full of people with perfect
hindsight, we also need to ask questions about the lessons that
should be learned.
I am concerned that, over the years since the MPC was
established, an increasing emphasis has been given to model
forecasts, and I worry that the MPC has gone too far in this
direction. Forecasts must be used with care, and model forecasts
should not be the only guide to decisions. They have to be looked
at, as several other speakers have said, alongside a range of
other indicators: monetary and financial measures, as well as
labour market pressures and, crucially, what is happening in
other countries and in world markets generally. It is also
advisable to spend time understanding the source of errors in the
recent past and whether they have clues to the future.
Reading the Bank's monetary reports, I have a further worry. The
forecasts are presented as the forecasts of the MPC itself. It
takes collective ownership of the process and the forecasts, but
I am not sure how a group of this size with several part-time
outside members can do this effectively. Surely it would be
better if the forecasts were owned by an executive forecasting
team, and the MPC would then take them into account, along with
other forecasts, analysis and insights, in making its
decisions.
This leads me to the concern in the committee's report that there
might be an absence of challenge, and the issue of intellectual
diversity. I would like to see the minutes include contributions
from individual members of the MPC, setting out briefly why, on
balance, they have reached their decision and the main factors
they have considered. We have the votes but not the reasons for
the votes set out in a systematic way.
Recently, I have been looking at some of the published minutes of
the monthly monetary meetings that took place between the
Chancellor and governor in the pre-independence era. One
interesting feature there is the extent of the challenge between
the main participants—what came to be known as the “Ken and Eddie
show”. At the end of those meetings, first the governor and then
the Chancellor would summarise the balancing of the factors and
their views on whether to change interest rates. There are some
useful ideas here about how this could work for members of the
MPC, so that we could hear rather more about the balancing
process, rather than this astonishing degree of agreement most of
the time.
My final group of concerns is around the issue of operational
independence versus policy independence. In its initial form in
1997, the emphasis was very much on operational independence,
with the Chancellor setting policy through the remit and the
inflation target. With the extension and greater complexity of
the remit, and with the emergence of QE and QT, this distinction
has become, to my mind, much more blurred. For example, once the
inflation rate is outside the normal tolerance band, it seems to
me that there is an important question of who should decide the
speed for aiming to return inflation to its target. For me, this
is as much a policy question as it is an operational question.
Surely the Chancellor should be more actively involved in this
issue than we have observed.
There is a similar issue about governance surrounding QE and QT,
and there is a clear role for both, as temporary measures under
extreme circumstances, to occur. We saw the success particularly
during the international financial crisis. However, since the
onset of Covid, it has been done in a way that has been pointed
out by several speakers: it has logged up huge mark-to-market
losses and higher debt interest costs. We have still had no
answer to the questions: “What account was taken of the potential
fiscal costs when the decisions were made, who should have been
the decision-makers and who should have been bearing the
risk?”
The Bank sees QE as a monetary operation and therefore one for
it. But the Treasury, of course, provides the Bank with an
indemnity for any losses. This suggests to me that this is a
policy question as well as an operational matter, and I am
surprised that there appears to be no established or regular
mechanism between the Bank and the Treasury for looking at the
fiscal risks involved in a policy that is as extensive as it has
been.
Finally, the Bernanke report set out many criticisms of the
forecasting hardware of the Bank and the failure to monitor and
maintain some parts of it. Along with the noble Baroness, Lady
Lane-Fox, who mentioned this, I find it deeply disappointing that
some of the basics of model building and the handling of digital
information should be ignored when the model itself is given such
a prominent role. I hope that we will see the kind of investment
that is needed there if we are to bring that into the modern
age.
1.05pm
(Con)
My Lords, it is a pleasure to follow the noble Lord, , in this extremely interesting
debate. I too thank my noble friend for securing it, and all the
committee members for their work on this thorough and interesting
report. I congratulate my noble friend on his excellent maiden
speech, with which, as noble Lords will hear, I have a good deal
of sympathy in many areas.
I will make two points, one minor and one major. The minor point
is one that other noble Lords have mentioned: the committee's
recommendations on the need for intellectual diversity in the
Bank. It is still surprising that Bank officials and the MPC
missed the significance of monetary policy in 2020 and 2021, and
more intellectual diversity would surely have made this less
likely. I would use the word “dismissive” rather than
“defensive”, which my friend used. The rather dismissive
responses from the Chancellor and the governor suggest that they
have not really taken this point on board. Indeed, perhaps they
rather missed it by simply reiterating the existing processes and
justifying them on the grounds of other kinds of diversity. As
other noble Lords have said, since the report we have had the
Bernanke review, with its heavy criticism of the modelling and
forecasting, which perhaps reinforces the committee's concerns.
Perhaps the Minister, in responding, could indicate whether there
is any chance of a rethink in this area.
I move to my major point. Although, like the committee and, I
think, most noble Lords, I support Bank independence, one must
acknowledge that, over the last couple of decades, central banks
have, in practice, come to enjoy great economic powers with
rather little accountability, scrutiny or democratic legitimacy.
That is not generally because the Government have chosen to give
them these powers—in this country at least. The gradual widening
of the Bank's mandate, set out so clearly by the committee, is a
consequence rather than the cause of this development. The real
underlying cause is the mistakes in global economic policy-making
over this period. I will take a moment to spell this out a little
more deeply. In doing so, I am in part indebted to the analysis
of my friend, the brilliant economist Bernard Connolly, in his
latest book.
Central banks and Governments the world over are now in a very
difficult position because of policy mistakes over the last
couple of decades. In brief, in the late 1990s and early 2000s,
the Fed, and other central banks following it, held rates too low
for too long and generated an unsustainable boom. When this
became obvious, central banks had a choice between creating a
recession by raising rates to choke it out or avoiding this by
pushing rates down. That was an extremely political choice for a
central bank to have to make. There was only one possible answer
it could give in a democracy: to push rates down. This in turn
generated another bubble, the credit bubble, which fed through to
asset prices, which in turn collapsed in 2008. Central banks
faced the same political choice, and again pushed rates down,
this time to zero or sub-zero.
In 2020, we had the third crisis. The same choice was faced and
the same solution was taken. Although there has been much
criticism of the Bank for its massive boost to QE in 2020, I do
not entirely blame the Bank authorities. I have vivid
recollections of the atmosphere of panic and crisis in No. 10 at
that time, as the economy came close to having a heart attack.
Hindsight is a wonderful thing, and I am not sure the central
banks could have taken any other decision at that point. The
question is more: how did they handle the consequences and how
quickly did they realise that some unwinding was necessary?
The negative supply shocks plus the huge US fiscal stimulus—let
us not forget that—meant that there was finally a feeding through
to inflation, which has had to be choked off by an effort at
normalisation. Of course, we now have a financial structure, as
we discovered in 2022, that has become used to very low long
rates and is vulnerable if there is a sudden adjustment towards
equilibrium. Hence the current situation. What can we do about
it?
We can look at our economic performance, and one conclusion that
I, and I think others, draw is that western economies generally
cannot live with interest rates that would have been considered
normal a generation ago, unless there is huge fiscal stimulus.
That is a very serious problem, which opens the question of how
long central banks generally, and the Bank of England
specifically, can sustain the current near-normalisation. The
impact of the US stimulus is now weakening and, very soon,
central banks will face the same choice once again: will they
hold rates relatively high, at the cost of a recession, or bring
them back down, as so many are now urging, at the price of
sustaining the imbalances and building them up further?
I have set this out at some length to underline just how
political the decisions are that the Bank, and central banks
generally, have had to take in recent years. Independent central
banks may have started off as providers of inflation control
services for Governments, but they now do much more than that.
The political decisions that they have taken, in each case to
defer difficult economic problems, have generated an environment
in which we can only avoid liquidation and recession with
super-low interest rates. Yet capitalism, as we have come to
understand it, cannot function with super-low interest rates. The
normal incentives do not work; there is malinvestment; asset
holders are enriched and risk takers lose out; and—we are seeing
this very much now—support for the system continually erodes,
such that we have a whole generation now ready to take a punt on
socialism.
Where do we go from here? I think that there are two routes. The
first, which I think it is the route cautiously, or implicitly,
suggested in the committee report, is to accept this status quo,
recognise the broader political power exercised by the Bank and
try to give it some enhanced democratic scrutiny from this
Parliament. I understand the logic, but I am slightly unconvinced
about the constitutionality of such arrangements. It seems to me
that it is for the Government to get the relationship right with
the Bank. That perhaps will, and ought to, involve more vigorous
debate in public, within the framework of bank independence, than
we have got used to. Then Parliament should scrutinise the
Government on how well they are managing that relationship and
its results, in terms of both fiscal and monetary policy.
I also fear the consequences of simply accepting the status quo.
It is a palliative, and a fig leaf for a situation that is, as I
have said, really very unsatisfactory. If we continue to repeat
the cycle of the past couple of decades, we will end up with
continued fiscal stimulus, ballooning debt, accelerating
inflation once again, greater government control of the economy,
greater direction of investment and business efforts and, in the
end, very likely a quasi-socialist economic system.
The alternative is to try to roll things back, to limit the Bank
to focusing much more narrowly and specifically on inflation
control again, and to find a way of dealing with the economic
consequences of the normalisation that would follow. This would
at least be to deal with causes not symptoms, but to make it work
would mean a major effort to raise the productive capacity and
potential growth of this economy through a radical programme of,
if you like, “recapitalismisation”—an ugly word, but an important
reality. That would mean huge deregulation; a determined and
sustained effort to get tax and spending down; and an end to the
crushing burden of net zero, planning reform, labour market
liberalisation and much more. Perhaps we will also get lucky with
AI and it will, as so many hope, give us a magic free gift in
productivity increase. I suspect, however, at least over our time
horizon, that it is unlikely to do more than smooth off the edges
of the turbulence of reform. Embarking on such a reform programme
would, in my view, be the right thing to do, but it would require
careful planning and a Government who were ready to explain it,
win a mandate for it and push it through. Noble Lords will have
their own views on how likely such an outcome is.
To conclude, formal bank independence is one thing, and it is
important, but the most important thing is to discuss, debate and
engage with the underlying political and economic reality. No
Government, of any political colour, can avoid that, or abdicate
their responsibility for managing the economy with the central
bank and ensuring proper democratic engagement in the
consequences. We have not had that properly for some time, but we
have some extremely difficult choices coming, so we will need it
in future.
1.15pm
of Coatdyke (Lab)
My Lords, I compliment the noble Lord, of Chelsea, for a very
interesting maiden speech. I am sure that we will hear an awful
lot more from him in the months and years that lie ahead.
I must start with a confession: I took the Bank of England Bill
through the Commons in 1998 and now, more than 25 years later, I
sit on the Economic Affairs Committee. It is good to be able to
look and see how the Bank has performed such a dramatic change of
role, but particularly at a time when, as the report says, there
is a real opportunity for change and to ensure that issues are
dealt with in a more modern and inclusive manner.
The decision to give the Bank operational independence had not
been announced during the general election campaign. I, as the
brand new Economic Secretary to the Treasury—a job that I had not
been shadowing, given that I was a comparatively new MP, having
come in in a by-election—heard of it for the first time when the
Chancellor announced it to the governor and his Treasury civil
servants. I overheard one of them say, “This is what it feels
like to be governed”. It was quite a dramatic turnaround.
Fortunately, I had a background as an economist and economic
reporter for the BBC, so I knew a little bit about it, but I had
to get up to speed—so I convinced my old friend to go for a Thai curry
that night. The advice that he gave me was, “Watch the
DMO—setting up the Debt Management Office is probably the most
difficult thing that you will have to do”. I think that he was
proved right. I think that I and some of the civil servants who
worked on it made mistakes, because we did not fully understand
how the market worked. That is my confession.
We nevertheless took the legislation through, and the
independence of the Back of England has been a very good success.
There have been areas that have not worked out because of
changing circumstances but, overall, it has ensured that
political interference has more or less gone away—I will come
back to that later. The Economic Affairs Committee is united in
support for the preservation of that independence. There is,
however, a recognition—as our chair, the noble Lord, , pointed out—that public
confidence in the Bank has fallen in the face of global and
domestic instability, which has seen the Bank not meet the 2%
target for inflation over the past two years. Errors in monetary
policy have added to the shocks brought about by Covid, Ukraine
and international instability, although the Bank is not the only
central bank that is having to deal with these issues.
There are a number of issues that are needed to restore
confidence in the Bank, and we outlined some of them, but I want
to concentrate on the relationship between the Bank and the
Treasury, which the noble Lord, , mentioned in his opening
speech. There are challenges of groupthink. At various stages of
my career, I have been part of the groupthink, and sometimes you
have to find mechanisms to break out of it. I also want to look
at the work of Dr Bernanke, who was commissioned to look at
forecasting and whose report was published, as we know, a few
weeks ago. I was very interested in what the noble Baroness, Lady
Lane-Fox, said about the concentration he put on computers. I am
more or less technologically illiterate, but even I knew that any
big, world famous institution really had to look at modernising
its computer systems, and I am shocked that that did not happen
at the Bank and that Bernanke found that the Bank was behind the
rest of the world.
When the noble Lord, , gave evidence to the
committee, he brought along the letter sent to the Bank of
England setting out the responsibilities of the Bank by , as Chancellor of the
Exchequer. The letter was one page and about four short
paragraphs long; enough to make it clear that, in return for
operational independence, the Bank had to meet the inflation
target. He then produced the current letter from Chancellor Hunt,
which was many pages long and added a list of issues the Bank had
to “have regard to”, as we heard earlier. I could be unkind and
say that this is virtue signalling, but, frankly, it did look
more like a press release than a commitment to monetary and
fiscal stability. likened the “have regard”
issues to a Christmas tree, and he has a point. One of our
witnesses pointed out that the structure of DNA is fewer than 900
words—much shorter than the Bank of England letter.
I contend that the “have regard” issue is a diversion from the
core work of the Bank. The chair of the Court, David Roberts,
when he gave evidence, drew attention to 31 “have regards” that
the Bank had to take account of. It is the job of the Treasury to
develop fiscal policy and the job of the Bank to concentrate on
monetary policy. They should not be jammed together as if it is
an unsatisfactory mix and the Treasury is the boss. There has to
be an atmosphere, first, of challenge, and, secondly, of putting
to the people who know what they are doing one side of the job,
and the people who know what they are doing, the other side of
the job. That way will give a sense of reality.
There has been a lot of talk about quantitative easing. It has
made the Bank and the Treasury much more dependent, blurring
monetary and fiscal policy, and that leads to the need for a
memorandum of understanding between the two organisations to move
forward. Like other noble Lords, I have to ask why the Chancellor
has refused to make the deed of indemnity public. It would be
very valuable to see that deed of indemnity.
Underpinning this is the risk of groupthink. We know that there
has to be a close relationship between HMT and the Bank, but it
has to be an arm's-length exchange of views, rather than a
dictatorial one, and it is beginning to look a little like a
dictatorial one. I am not necessarily criticising the Treasury: I
loved working in the Treasury and I am in awe of some of the
officials I worked with—one or two of whom ended up as deputy
governors of the Bank—but it is so important that that separation
is remembered.
Finally, let me say that there needs to be a diversity of thought
and culture within the Bank. said that the Bank may be
independent, but the Treasury casts a shadow over it. There has
to be an independent review of how that can be addressed, and
there should be, as Bernanke's report and our report point out, a
look at how other public appointments are made, looking for best
practice. I think the number of non-executive directors on the
Court of the Bank needs to be expanded, because you need
challenge. Anybody who has run a reasonably big organisation
knows how important challenge is, and there seems to have been an
environment that limited the extent to which there could be
challenge. I look forward to the future of the Bank. I think the
claim for independence that comes out in the report, and came out
in our witness statements, make it clear that it was the right
decision at the right time.
1.25pm
(Con)
My Lords, I was a member of your Lordships' Economic Affairs
Committee when this report was produced last year, and I am
delighted that my noble friend of Headley has been able to
secure this debate today.
As we have heard, the Bank of England acquired independence in
relation to monetary policy as one of the Labour Government's
first acts in 1987. At the time, I was a non-executive director
on the Court of the Bank of England and so had something of a
ringside seat as this unfolded. It was hugely popular in the Bank
and, I believe, with almost all the commentators at the time.
The Bank of England was not and is not completely independent of
the Government. When it was nationalised in 1947, the Bank of
England Act gave the Government various powers over the Bank,
including the power to appoint the governor, the deputy
governor—who was a singleton at the time, but there are now
four—and its Court of Directors.
As was common for nationalisation legislation, which we have
fortunately not seen much of in recent years, the Act contained a
power of direction that can be exercised by the Treasury,
although this does not extend to monetary policy. That power has
never actually been used but, when I tried, during the passage of
last year's Financial Services and Markets Bill, to get the
Treasury to give it up, it was absolutely sure it needed to keep
it, so we must regard this power of direction as a live part of
the constitution of the Bank of England. My point is that this
means that the Bank of England has only qualified
independence—but, importantly, the extent of its independence is
in the hands of the Government and of Parliament.
Similarly, monetary policy independence is not absolute, either.
The members of the MPC are appointed by the Government and
statute defines the monetary policy objective—that of price
stability. That is then amplified by letters from the Treasury
which, inter alia, tell the Bank what price stability means: that
is where we get the inflation rate target. This is just a
roundabout way of saying that I do not think we should overstate
Bank of England independence. It is not absolute but is always
bounded by political decisions. I agree with what the noble Lord,
, said about QE raising the
important issue of whether further political decisions should be
taken to change the scope of the Bank's independence as we define
it.
Our report set out to find out how independence was working in
practice. In the inflationary turmoil of the last few years, it
is easy to forget that the UK experienced a relatively long
period of low and largely stable inflation, from the early 1990s
until 2020. It would be wrong, however, to give the credit for
that to Bank of England independence. First, my noble friend
, as he explained earlier,
introduced in 1992 the concept of publicly targeting the
inflation rate. By the time the Bank was given independence in
relation to monetary policy, inflation was already at its then
target rate of 2.5% in terms of RPI. So the Bank did not bring
inflation down. Secondly, as evidence to the committee made
plain, there were other factors at play—in particular, the impact
of globalisation, which created a benign price environment. None
of our witnesses claimed that the years of low and stable
inflation were down to central bank independence.
We also looked at the strength of the independence model in light
of the inflation experience of the last three years, which has
clearly been less than impressive. The model appeared to do well
for the first 20-odd years, but more recently it has been tested
and found wanting. There have been serious misjudgments about
whether the inflation spike which emerged was temporary, and we
are still a way off the 2% target, as the OECD charmingly
reminded us this morning.
As we have heard, the Bank's forecasting record is not stellar.
An independent review within the Bank in 2015 found that, while
the Bank appeared to be in the pack with other central banks, its
two-year horizon forecast—the important one in bringing inflation
down within target—had, to use the bank-speak in which the report
was written,
“statistically significant evidence of inefficiency”.
I think that means that the Bank was not very good at it, and its
recent experience has raised even more questions.
As we have heard, last year the Bank commissioned an external
review by Dr Bernanke, the former chair of the Fed. The Bank
should take credit for that. The conclusion of the report was
that the models needed a serious overhaul, and that it needed to
move towards more scenario analysis and away from fan charts.
However, the narrowness of its terms of reference, which has
already been referred to, meant that it did not shed any real
light on what went wrong.
As has already been referred to in this debate, several of our
witnesses drew attention to what was happening to money
supply—fuelled by the continuing QE—in the two years or so before
inflation took off. But this barely got a mention by the Bank or
MPC members at the time. Some serious thought about what was
happening would have been useful, but the Bank is part of a
global central bank consensus that has largely ignored money
supply for a considerable period of time. I was disappointed, but
not surprised, to find that the Bernanke report made no comment
on this.
The committee's conclusion that the Bank's independence should be
preserved was in line with that of our witnesses, but I think the
conclusion owes more to sentiment than to hard evidence of the
success of the model. I am not arguing that monetary policy
independence should be done away with, but we need to see it as a
pragmatic judgment which suits politicians and central bankers
alike, rather than one with a firm evidence base, and we should
be prepared to modify what we mean by independence as new facts
emerge.
Of course, the key issue becomes whether the accountability
framework surrounding the Bank is strong enough to underpin
continuing monetary policy independence. I believe that the Bank
failed the British people when it let inflation get out of
control, but what has happened as a result of that? The governor
has had a few uncomfortable appearances before parliamentary
committees, and he has had to write a few letters to the
Chancellor. Who takes responsibility for the dire state of
modelling found in the Bernanke report? Who carries the can for
the damage inflicted on the economy from excessive inflation and
the resulting interest rate hikes? It seems that no one does.
I believe that there is outstanding business here. The Government
have confirmed their commitment to monetary policy independence,
but independence cannot exist in a vacuum. The Government need to
reflect on whether that independence has sufficient checks and
balances built into it, because independence without strong
accountability is a recipe for disaster. The modest
recommendation in our report is for a five yearly review by
Parliament, and that would be a very good start.
1.34pm
(CB)
My Lords, I too was a member of the committee that produced this
report, and I declare an interest, in every sense of that word,
as a former Governor of the Bank. In addition to welcoming the
noble Lord, , I also pay tribute to the
noble Lord, , for his chairmanship of the
committee, and the way he brought us all together when assessing
the evidence from an impressive array of witnesses.
I want to make just three points. First, I believe that
operational independence of the Bank has served the country well.
When I joined the Bank in 1991, interest rates could change at
any moment, on any day, at the whim of the Prime Minister or
Chancellor. They often reflected political considerations. If a
Budget was well received by the markets, the Government would
reward themselves with a cut in bank rate. If circumstances
suggested that a rise in bank rate would be sensible, it was
postponed until after an election. I remember a meeting between
governor and Chancellor—I stress not the noble Lord, , but another Chancellor—where
the Chancellor began the meeting by saying “I want to make it
clear that there will be no rise in interest rates today, but
having said that, I'd now like to hear the evidence”.
A much more systematic approach to monetary policy was adopted
after our exit from the exchange rate mechanism in 1992 under the
noble Lord, . An inflation target was
introduced, and monthly meetings were held according to a
pre-announced timetable. The Bank had a genuinely free voice
through its new quarterly inflation report. These were very
important changes, but it was only with the announcement of
operational independence in May 1997 that the risk premium in
long-term interest rates fell sharply, as the belief that
political motives would influence the degree and timing of
interest rates was removed.
Several speakers have referred to the Bank's record since 1992,
and there is no doubt that the noble Baroness, Lady Noakes, is
right in stressing that it was not just in 1997 that the good
inflation performance began; the Bank's record between 1992 and
1997 played a role in leading to independence. But in the past
few years, that record has clearly been tarnished by the rise in
inflation to a peak of 11.1%. That leads me to my second point,
stressed earlier in this debate, about the lack of intellectual
diversity on the Monetary Policy Committee. Over its lifetime,
there has not been a real lack of intellectual diversity on the
MPC. We have seen many split votes; I was in a minority on two
occasions as governor. More recently, after Covid arrived, at the
point when it really mattered, we did not see a good deal of
challenge to the prevailing narrative.
There continues to be a good deal of disagreement on the causes
of the recent rise and subsequent fall in inflation. But many
economists, both here and in the United States, pointed to the
likely impact of a very substantial monetary and fiscal expansion
boosting aggregate demand, at a time when the measures introduced
to counteract Covid were lowering aggregate supply. Too much
money chasing too few goods is, and always has been, a recipe for
inflation. It is troubling that not just on the Monetary Policy
Committee, but also on the Federal Reserve Open Market Committee
there were no dissenting voices to challenge the view that
inflation was transitory.
This lack of challenge is certainly not confined to the Bank of
England. The academic economics profession has essentially
jettisoned the idea that, from time to time, one should ask what
the growth rate of broad money was telling us, especially at a
time when, as in the United States, it was rising at the fastest
rate at any point since the Second World War. The excessive
reliance on models that ignored money altogether was somewhat
foolish.
In 2020-21, when inflation started to rise, there was not a
single dissenting vote on the MPC and no mention of the monetary
data in the Bank's reports. Bank rate exceeded its pre-pandemic
level only in May 2022. I understand why this groupthink came
about—because that had become an academic consensus—but,
unfortunately, its impact on monetary policy led to the problems
that we are now too familiar with.
Some commentators have concluded that a different way of
presenting the Bank's forecasts might solve these problems—which,
I think, was the implicit suggestion of Ben Bernanke's report—but
the mistakes of 2020-21 were not the result of presentation.
While the Bank used fan charts and the Federal Reserve used dot
plots, it did not make any difference; they both made the same
misjudgment. What really matters are judgments about the state of
the economy and the way that monetary policy works. Our
recommendation is to focus on the need for genuine intellectual
diversity and, to meet that point, reform of the appointments
process to senior positions in the Bank.
My third point concerns the mandate and remit given by the
Chancellor and Parliament to the Bank. Since 2013, the Bank has
acquired responsibilities for prudential regulation of banks and
insurance companies, and has an even wider responsibility for
financial stability through the Financial Policy Committee. It is
also the resolution authority for the United Kingdom. Those new
tasks have increased the number of staff in the Bank from under
2,000 to over 5,000, with an inevitable reduction in focus on its
monetary policy mission. As others have said, the expansion of
responsibilities has gone further with the introduction into its
mandate of issues such as climate change, the competitiveness of
the City and other secondary objectives.
The expansion of central bank mandates makes it more likely that
governors will start to behave as politicians and try to
cultivate popularity through venturing into areas well outside
monetary policy. Trying to keep inflation close to the target and
maintaining the stability of the financial system is more than
enough for one institution. As many of our witnesses pointed out,
climate change policy is a matter for government, and, frankly,
it is ridiculous to suggest that central banks can have any major
impact on it. Therefore, there needs to be a cull of the
additional secondary objectives, remit letters and “have regards
to” obligations imposed on the Bank since independence was
granted in 1997. Too many responsibilities make it difficult for
senior people in the Bank to think strategically.
Concerns about the lack of intellectual diversity and the burden
of excessive responsibilities are not arguments against central
bank independence. Rather, they are the opposite: they point to
reforms that can reinforce independence and restore the mission
of the Bank of England to ensure the stability of prices and the
financial system. Whichever party forms the next Government, I
hope that it will take a careful look at our report.
1.43pm
(Con)
My Lords, I welcome the opportunity to contribute to this debate
on the report from the committee of which I am honoured to be a
member. I am also very honoured to follow the speech by the noble
Lord, Lord King, who has a very distinguished record, and the
excellent maiden speech by the noble Lord, .
Although much in the report is critical of the Bank of England, I
will start, as others have, by recognising that the Bank is
staffed by public servants who endeavour to do their best in the
role that we have given them. The problem is ours, in that we
have delegated responsibilities to them with expectations that
are beyond what unelected officials can properly deliver.
The actions of the Bank in its control of monetary policy have
huge implications for the state of the economy and the welfare of
British citizens. Monetary policy has been given the sole target
of controlling inflation, but it is an illusion to think that it
can just act on inflation in isolation. By acting on interest
rates and aggregate demand, the decisions of the Bank can create
economic booms or recessions, can inflate or deflate asset prices
with resultant changes in the distribution of wealth, and has a
huge impact on the daily mortgage costs, interest payments and
living standards of everyone in the country. Since independence,
those critical decisions have been entrusted to a small group of
unelected officials, who, because they are independent, are not
subject to significant challenge or accountability from
government or Parliament. It is the issue of accountability on
which I will focus.
Putting such important economic decisions in the hands of expert
officials might make sense if economics were a precise science.
Unlike science, where the variables are inert agents that can be
reliably modelled, the movement of the economy reflects the
decisions and interactions of human beings and their expectations
and state of mind, as the noble Lord, , said. There is no equation
that can reliably predict the kinetics of how an economy in
disequilibrium will respond to specific policy initiatives or
anticipate the impact of unknown world events. The search for a
perfect forecasting model is doomed to failure.
In the absence of a perfect forecast, the decisions of the Bank
of England require judgments about not just the forecasts but the
potential risks and benefits of alternative actions on the
population and its standard of living. One would think that such
important trade-offs are properly the preserve of democratic
institutions that are answerable to the public for their
political choices. What is more, it is fanciful to suggest that
monetary policy can operate completely independently of
government fiscal policy, because, in the short term, the two
economic policy levers impact on the same economic variables,
either stimulating or contracting the real economy. The Bank of
England's actions can work either with or to counteract the
fiscal policy of the Government. If the two are not co-ordinated,
we will not get the optimal outcome.
The Bank of England's decisions are therefore in many respects
ultimately political rather than just technocratic judgments. It
is not fair to ask unelected officials to take responsibility for
political judgments, nor right or proper in a democracy with an
elected Government. Government and Parliament exercise power over
many other important policy areas, including national defence and
the ability to declare war, so it is not clear to me why we
entrust our elected Government with those decisions but feel it
uniquely necessary to exclude them from this one component of
economic policy.
Nevertheless, I accept that the doctrine of central bank
independence is now hard to row back from, and I recognise that
the idea that independence protects the economy from
irresponsible government policies has been welcomed and is baked
into the bond markets. Even so, it is not sensible or necessary
for the two economic levers of monetary and fiscal policy to be
decided at arm's length. We heard evidence in the committee that
working-level engagement between the Bank and the Treasury is
carefully controlled to avoid any impression that the Government
and the Treasury are seeking to influence the Bank. That is an
unnecessary constraint.
During the 1990s, before Bank of England independence, I was
fortunate to have been the Prime Minister's representative in the
regular working meetings between the Bank of England and Treasury
officials in the office of the then Permanent Secretary to the
Treasury, now the noble Lord, . These allowed all the economic
issues to be debated openly between the Bank and the Treasury,
with all the relevant information. Although, as the noble Lord,
, described, the final decision
on monetary policy then rested on agreement between the governor
and the Chancellor, any attempt to push the then governor, Eddie
George, into going along with something he thought was improper
would have been halted in its tracks by the threat of
resignation, and I am sure the same would have been true of his
successor, the noble Lord, Lord King. One step we can take is to
break down the unnecessary Chinese walls and recreate sensible,
open engagement between the Bank and the Treasury. I hope that my
noble friend the Minister will take this on board.
I remind the House that, as the noble Baroness, Lady Noakes,
pointed out, the era of low inflation was initiated during this
period before Bank of England independence rather than being a
consequence of independence. If we are unable to unwind the Bank
of England's independence, we should consider how we can make the
appointed officials more accountable to Parliament for their
decisions.
As others have set out, the Bank has not had a glorious record in
recent years, underlining the need for greater scrutiny and
accountability. I argue that, based on the previous governor's
theory of excess global savings, interest rates were kept too low
for too long in the years before the pandemic, which, together
with a huge increase in money supply through QE, led to
unsustainable increases in asset prices. The messaging that low
interest rates were the new norm also led individuals to take on
borrowings that left them cruelly exposed. As a result, it is
arguable that the delayed high-scale increase in rates that the
Bank then had to adopt was also more damaging than it needed to
be. Like any system, the reaction of the economy to a sudden,
large shock is more violent and damaging than a gradual change
that gives people time to adjust their finances.
Since the trigger for inflation was the massive increase in
external prices from the pandemic and the war in Ukraine, real
incomes and aggregate demand had already been depressed. If the
inflation was not initially caused by excess demand, although
facilitated by the money supply, the conventional theory that a
further squeeze on living standards was required is itself open
to debate. We no longer include mortgage costs in the favoured
consumer prices index, but the rapid, steep rise in interest
rates, by contributing to pressures on household incomes, may
itself have been a factor in increasing pressure for higher wage
increases. In short, the Bank of England's actions may well have
been responsible for a larger, longer and more painful drag on
the economy and living standards than could have been achieved
with different policies and different judgments.
Since the Government cannot be the judge for the actions of an
independent Bank, that task must fall to Parliament. As set out
in the report, there is a strong case for more effective
parliamentary scrutiny, including a five-yearly review and
perhaps a Standing Committee of both Houses, with permanent
technical support that can engage in a more timely way and
satisfy itself that the full range of options and implications
have been properly considered. I would go further and suggest
that in holding the Bank to account for its actions, such a
committee could have the remit to report to Parliament if it no
longer has confidence in the Governor of the Bank of England. The
structure of parliamentary accountability may not be within the
control of my noble friend the Minister, but I hope the
Government will lend their support to such proposals.
In conclusion, I accept that these suggestions may not be
welcomed by those who hold Bank of England independence as an act
of faith, but the extent of the delegated powers now exercised by
unelected officials without proper accountability cannot be
right. If we cannot reverse that decision, we must take action to
enable it to operate with a framework that provides better
democratic control.
1.52pm
of Manor Castle (GP)
My Lords, I thank the noble Lord, of Headley, for introducing
this debate and thank the Economic Affairs Committee for its
report, some of which I agree with and some of which I strongly
disagree with.
There are two themes in my remarks, addressing two key elements
of the committee's report: the lack of intellectual diversity in
the Bank and its climate remit. I must begin by noting the lack
of diversity in the discussions in your Lordships' House today. I
would love to see more noble Lords who focus on poverty, workers'
rights, the environment and the place of small and medium-sized
enterprises and regional economies in debates such as this. There
has been a high degree of groupthink in our debate today—that is
true across our politics, of course, and there is a lack of
democracy across all our structures. I acknowledge that I am
addressing these remarks to noble Lords who are not in this
Chamber rather than those who are here and speaking today.
I want to address the committee directly, because I took a
careful look at the list of those who gave testimony to it. One
name stuck out—Positive Money—on whose works my remarks today
draw, but other than that, I find it curious that no name that
leapt out at me was a climate expert or a climate finance expert.
I found no reference to the committee consulting with our own
Environment and Climate Change Committee. I respectfully put to
the committee that in future, if it is going to comment on
climate issues and make them a central part of its report, it
might want to focus on more diverse testimony.
That is in the intellectual context in which debate on the Bank
of England is highly siloed. If we look at much of the commentary
around the actions of the Bank in 2021 and 2022, the criticism
that we have heard very often today is that, as inflation reached
its peak, the Bank was too slow to act. However, interest rate
rises cannot address the main driver of the inflation that we
have seen—that is, the dependence of our economy on fossil fuels
that are priced in a highly volatile way. Much of the criticism
and some of what we have heard today has been based on the flawed
theory that inflation has been due to a wage-price spiral.
It is too often ignored that rate hikes have highly unequal
impacts. They attempt to bring down inflation by reducing
spending. The poorest and most indebted are the most affected,
while the incomes of those with savings and the profits of the
banking sector are increased. Crucially, in the climate context,
the rate rises have added to the downside of the investments that
we desperately need, because many green projects require a large
amount of upfront investment, despite the fact that we will all
profit from the cheaper prices of the energy generation of the
reductions in bills from insulation, et cetera. Also, we live in
a society of crumbling infrastructure—housing, roads and many
other issues.
The commentary of the Lords committee, with which I respectfully
disagree, suggests that giving the Monetary Policy Committee and
the relevant policy committee a remit on climate change risks
drawing the Bank into the Government's wider policy agenda and
jeopardises the Bank's ability to prioritise price and financial
stability. It is worth going into the history of this. It is a
demonstration that campaigning works that, in 2021, the
Government's target of reaching net zero was included in the
Government's letters to all key policy-making committees for the
first time. It was a step signalling the Government's support for
ambitious action to steer the financial flows away from harmful
sources such as fossil fuels and towards green and sustainable
industries.
Critics will say, and I would entirely agree, that central bank
policies alone are no silver bullet for environmental crises, but
central banks have a central role. Think of those core
priorities—those objectives of price and financial stability.
There is no stability on a dying planet. The economy is a
complete subset of the environment, 100% dependent on it, rather
than on complex equations unattached to the real world or
assumptions that all resources are either infinite or
replaceable. No, they are not. The practical reality is that the
UK financial sector continues to pour money into new fossil fuels
despite the reality of the carbon bubble and the huge financial
risk that represents, while relying on climate risk models that
fundamentally do not accurately translate into the complexity of
the financial risk. That is looking only at climate. I would also
point to the fact that the Bank needs to look more widely at all
the other planetary boundaries that we have exceeded. We are
seeing a great deal of focus at the moment on novel
entities—pesticides, pharmaceuticals and plastics—and there are
huge financial risks in that area as well.
To put this in a broader frame, the UK financial and economic
system remains highly vulnerable to “fossilflation” while at the
same time the impacts of climate change, such as on our food
supply, are already causing “climateflation”. I coin another
word, “shockflation”. We are in an age of shocks—the geopolitics
are very obviously extremely unstable—and all these things must
be considered in the round rather than simply looking at the
economy as a set of equations sitting outside this.
We also have too much finance, too much money going into the
financial sector rather than the real economy, just as most of
the money from quantitative easing went into raising inequality,
making the few richer and the rest of us poorer—much as it was
needed, at least at the start, to tackle the chaos created by the
greed and fraud of the bankers. The Bank, the Treasury and the
Government are far too dependent on failed, outdated models and
mathematical equations which bear no resemblance to the real
world.
I move to the present day and the open letter, dated 16 March,
referring to the remarks made by the Governor of the Bank of
England to the Lords Economic Affairs Committee, that the Bank
has reduced its resourcing for climate emergency work, to which
the noble Baroness, Lady Lane-Fox, referred. The timing of these
remarks—this action—could not be worse in a world that is on
fire, awash and melting. I have a direct question for the
Minister and, indeed, the Labour Front Bench. Will they support
the calls by so many eminent economists in a letter—I declare
that the Green Party's spokesperson, Molly Scott Cato, was among
the signatories—to reprioritise work in the Bank to align the
financial sector with the Government's climate goals, reversing
the resource cuts and to reassert the Bank of England as a
climate leader, as a matter of urgency?
I shall briefly address the issue of the Bank's intellectual
diversity. It is not independent of failed ideology and a
discipline that has simply run out of road. During the 2016
Brexit referendum campaign, I suggested to my now-House
colleague, the noble Lord, , that the remain campaign
should stop saying “economists say”, because no believes them,
and that is even more the case now. Neo-classical economics is
the absolute opposite of systemic thinking; we need systematic,
scientific, sociologically and politically literate thinking in
the Bank and Treasury and across government. We are in the age of
post-growth; not only can we not have infinite growth on a finite
planet but we will not have growth in at least the coming decade.
To quote the IMF chief, the “tepid twenties” are with us.
On diversity, they will not thank me for this, but I will suggest
some names that the Bank of England should start drawing on:
Jason Hickel; Kate Raworth; Julia Steinberger; Ann Pettifor; Tim
Jackson and Judith Kirton-Darling. All of them spoke at the
post-growth conference in the European Parliament last year that
was backed by all but the far right group there. I shall hazard a
prediction that there were several future economics laureates
speaking there, with original thinking that is lacking in what is
regarded as the economic mainstream.
I will quickly raise one final issue with the Minister. The New
Economics Foundation states:
“The government could save £55bn over the next five years if it
limits the amount of money the Bank of England pays interest on
to commercial banks … The Treasury will pay out over £150bn to
the Bank of England to fund its payments to the banking sector by
2028, this on top of the £30bn already paid out in 2023”.
Surely, this is something that other countries are not doing and
that we did not do in the past, which we can reverse?
2.02pm
The (Con)
My Lords, I would like to thank my noble friend of Headley for securing this
important debate. I would also like to congratulate my noble
friend of Chelsea on his excellent
maiden speech. I have already enjoyed several discussions with
him, and I am very much looking forward to all his future
contributions. I should also highlight my entry in the register
of interests.
I count myself extremely lucky to have worked in financial
markets for 25 years, during which time I have had the privilege
of working with some of the brightest individuals in the country,
including a former employee of the Bank of England. It was
essential in my role to understand and be able to explain
currency forecasting in both the short, medium and long term. As
anyone who has been involved in currency forecasting, or indeed
any other type of economic modelling will know, it is notoriously
difficult. Alan Greenspan, when he was chairman of the Federal
Reserve in the 1990s, set his researchers the task of examining
foreign exchange rates and, having number-crunched 30 years'
worth of data, they concluded that it was impossible to predict.
It was therefore of interest to me that the committee report
suggested that a lack of intellectual diversity at the Bank
contributed to a misdiagnosis of recent inflationary pressures,
as well as inadequate forecasting and modelling techniques. I
agree with the report wholeheartedly: it is incredibly important
to have a diverse range of personalities, backgrounds and
experiences of both women and men that runs true in any business
and board of directors.
However, as I hope I have demonstrated briefly to your Lordships,
economic forecasting is challenging at the best of times. Even if
you did have a different membership make-up, which is a key
recommendation of the report and should happen regardless, the
likelihood of forecasting outsized shocks to the system may
increase only marginally.
It is a fact that many central banks other than the Bank of
England did not see inflation coming as aggressively as it did.
That is confirmed by Ben Bernanke's review, published last month,
when he said:
“A comparison of forecasting performance shows that virtually all
forecasters—both in central banks and outside—failed to
anticipate in a timely way the dramatic economic consequences of
the post-2019 shocks”.
Therefore, on the basis that it is extremely difficult to
forecast economic outcomes correctly, it would be highly
beneficial if the Bank could provide the public with regular and
alternative scenario analyses, aside from its main forecast,
potentially as well as a dot plot. Primarily, it would
demonstrate that the Bank is aware of and preparing for a variety
of different shocks and, as a result, is sparking diversity of
thought within the organisation and addressing preventive
measures. Additionally, given that financial markets hate
uncertainty, it provides those participants with the necessary
information to apply a more balanced approach to their own
potential future exposure models in different asset classes.
Lastly, it encourages a more regular two-way dialogue and
relationship between the Bank and its external stakeholders,
which is critical. It is essential to build that relationship,
communicate openly and challenge constructively where
appropriate.
I will also briefly highlight stress testing within forecasting.
Last Wednesday, the headline on the front page of the Financial
Times read:
“Lenders are in the dark over private equity risk, Bank of
England warns”.
The article continued:
“Exposure stress tests lacking … BoE regulator … said yesterday
that lenders should routinely stress test their exposure but
‘hardly any banks do it well'”,
referring to private equity exposure. It is of course entirely
correct to say that firms should routinely stress-test their
exposure; it is best market practice. But it is also essential
because so-called black swan events are no longer a rare
occurrence. Since the global financial crisis, we have seen the
ensuing Eurozone crisis, the unpegging of the Swiss franc,
Brexit, the pandemic, the war in Ukraine, the September 2022
fiscal event and heightened geopolitical risk in the Middle East.
Financial risk is omnipresent.
However, the Economic Affairs Committee report referred to Dr
Bernanke, who found that:
“Some key software used in preparing the forecasts is out of date
and lacks important functionality”
because
“insufficient resources have been devoted to ensuring that the
software and models underlying the forecast are adequately
maintained”.
If we follow the Bank's premise that everyone must stress test
well, which we should, it is vital that the Bank itself allocates
sufficient resource and headcount to guarantee that it is
employing up-to-date software and models.
Finally, the Bank plays a crucial role for every person in this
country. That is an extremely powerful office of authority. It is
right that it should be independent to ensure financial stability
and confidence in the UK economy, which has multiple ancillary
benefits to the population. However, as the report notes, that
power is concentrated among a small group of individuals. I
suggest that the Bank is as powerful as and has more
responsibility than any of the largest listed companies in the
UK, but they are answerable to shareholders. In this case, the
shareholders of the Bank are the people of the UK who are, in
turn, represented by elected government officials. While we must
retain the independence of the Bank in setting monetary policy,
we must also ensure that it is accountable to its
shareholders.
I therefore ask my noble friend the Minister whether the
Government will encourage the Bank, as a matter of urgency, to
replace its out-of-date software and functionality for
forecasting and stress testing. Will they ensure that the Bank
allocates resource internally to provide the public with both
more regular and supplementary forecasting scenario analyses?
Lastly, will they encourage the Bank to complete, within an
agreed fair and reasonable timeframe, the recommendations that
came out of Dr Bernanke's review?2.09pm
(CB)
My Lords, I thank the noble Lord, , for his skilful chairmanship
of the committee and the support we had from the start. I
congratulate the noble Lord, , on shoehorning so many
interesting insights into the conventional constraints of a
maiden speech.
In many ways, this was a difficult investigation. Serious
criticism was made of the Bank's performance by many serious
people, particularly for the period 2020 to 2022. The focus of
concern was that inflation, which had been kept close to 2% for
over 20 years, suddenly took off and the Bank appeared to have
lost control. By contrast, virtually no one advocated withdrawing
operational independence or dropping or even recalibrating the
inflation target. At least for now, the priority for the Bank was
seen to be to rebuild its credibility by getting inflation back
to 2% before looking at anything else.
What concerned the EAC was that we were repeatedly told by people
in the Bank that there was always robust debate in the MPC, and
alternative views were expressed. In March 2020, the Bank rate
was reduced to 0.1% and no change was made to interest rates for
18 months, until December 2021, and at that time all votes were
unanimous. During this period, inflation rose from 1.5% to around
5%, on its way to a peak of 11%, before the Bank reacted, and
even then it reacted only cautiously. Where was the robust
debate? In economics there is the concept of revealed preference:
look at what people do rather than what they say.
The dominant narrative was that, after Covid, the economy was
teetering on the verge of recession and inflation was likely to
stay low. The forces that had pushed prices up were labelled as
transitory: once the initial hit had ended, inflation would
return naturally to its previous level. What this narrative
missed was that there was a different story to be told: the sharp
rise in inflation reduced the incomes of families and companies,
and they would be anxious to try to recoup these losses, although
in doing so they would perpetuate inflation. Also, during the
Covid lockdown, people's and companies' bank balances—that is,
broad money—increased substantially, so as soon as they were
released to do so, households and companies started to spend
again and had the money to do so. This was before supply chains
could be fully restored. The result was a sharp rise in inflation
which is taking time to be brought under control.
What we have seen would be regarded as groupthink. Was there
enough diversity within the MPC to explore different scenarios,
raising questions about the process by which members are
selected? They say nostalgia is not what it used to be, but has
the inaugural MPC appointed in 1997 ever been bettered for its
range of experience?
In his memoirs, the late lamented Lord Lawson regretted the fact
that, in 1988, he had underestimated the strength of the recovery
and the upward pressure on prices. He particularly regretted the
use of the word “blip”. Did the present Governor of the Bank of
England make the same mistake with his use of the word
“transitory”? How was it that there was so much focus on the
narrative that interest rates needed to be kept low and so little
attention to an alternative scenario in which, with supply lines
disrupted, this sharp increase in spending would lead to a sharp
increase in inflation?
The answer may be found in the report the Bank commissioned from
Dr Bernanke on its forecasting. In it he drew attention to the
excessive focus on a central forecast and the lack of
investigation of alternative narratives. We should bear in mind
the maxim of George Eliot: prophecy is the most gratuitous form
of error. Dr Bernanke's recipe for this was that alternative
scenarios should be looked at more, as the Bank had failed to
realise that we were in a different world and that it was not in
Kansas any more.
In mitigation, the Bank has claimed that it did no worse than
other central banks. This may tell us that there was groupthink
within not only the Bank of England but the community of central
banks, all of which bought in heavily to the idea of a transitory
inflation increase, while their economies were teetering on the
edge of recession.
One of the issues addressed in the EAC report was the way the
remit letters of the MPC, FPC and PRC expanded, with a
proliferation of secondary objectives to be taken into account
and have regard to. The danger of this was that the focus on the
primary objective—containing inflation—would be diminished, and
management of resources would be spread more thinly. We therefore
recommended that these remit letters should be pruned—in
particular, that the references to the Government's objective of
net zero should be taken out. A number of our witnesses argued
that the Bank had no instruments that could be brought to bear on
the net-zero objectives, and that this should be left to the
Government. In response to our report, the Chancellor agreed with
this recommendation, although this has brought howls of protest
from environmental interests—more of which we heard only two or
three minutes ago. In our session with the Chancellor, we urged
him to go beyond a light trim of the remit letters, and to see
whether more radical pruning could be undertaken.
One of the trickiest issues we encountered, and to which we were
unable to develop a conclusive response, was the relationship
between fiscal and monetary policy. In 1997, it all looked
remarkably simple; the Treasury was responsible for fiscal
policy, and as a result took over responsibility for debt
management, and the Bank was responsible for the operation of
monetary policy and decisions on interest rates. In retrospect,
this clear separation was an oversimplification. As the noble
Lord, , has pointed out, monetary
policy has effects on the economy similar to fiscal policy, and
vice versa.
The use of QE has muddied the waters further. Although decisions
on the quantum of QE were ostensibly taken by the Bank as
extensions of its responsibility for monetary policy, this has
had a major impact on the distribution of income and wealth in
society, normally regarded as concerns of fiscal policy. QE
raised the value of assets for those who possessed them, and
increased the cost of acquiring assets for those who did not have
them, such as first-time buyers. QE has had major effects on the
structure of UK debt, making it much more vulnerable to movements
in short-term interest rates. The long length of UK maturities
had always been regarded as a major advantage of UK debt
management. As QE is unwound, there will be major losses, the
cost of which will fall to the Government. We need better
information on what those costs are.
I was surprised that both the Treasury and the Bank clung so
vehemently to the doctrine that fiscal policy was the Treasury's
domain and monetary policy was the Bank's domain, despite the
fact that the policy of each had implications for the other
party. Looking again in history, I am reminded that in 1993 the
then Chancellor, now the noble Lord, , consciously undertook an
exercise of rebalancing, because it was felt that our membership
of the ERM had forced us to hold interest rates higher than the
economy required, and that at the same time fiscal policy was too
loose. There was a conscious effort to ease monetary policy while
tightening fiscal policy.
The process of looking to find the optimum balance of policies
will be more difficult to achieve if each party sticks rigidly to
its own domain. Maybe what is happening is that the Chancellor
wants to avoid any possible submission that he is leaning on the
Bank to keep interest rates low in order to reduce the
Government's own debt servicing costs. But this pursuit of value
has the disadvantage that collaboration between the two
institutions is made more difficult. As I said, the committee was
unable to resolve this conundrum, so it remains in the to-do box
of both institutions.
2.19pm
(Con)
My Lords, I warmly welcome the report of my noble friend Lord
Bridges's Economic Affairs Committee. I will first look at the
recommendations, and the Bank's and the Government's reactions to
them. I will then consider the review by Dr Bernanke into the
Bank's forecast process, and finally give some thoughts of my own
on recent years' inflation and interest rate rises.
As the report states, the then Chancellor, , set up this new operational
independence after the 1997 general election. This had worked
well up until 2021, and inflation and interest rates had been
kept low.
The committee focused first on the interaction of monetary and
fiscal policy. I agree with its recommendation that there should
be
“clear lines of responsibility and effective communication
between the Bank and HM Treasury”,
especially that HM Treasury should promote
“a fiscal stance which supports the inflation target it has set
the Bank”,
particularly when interest rates are close to zero and the Bank
has limited space to loosen monetary policy further. I especially
support the committee's view that quantitative easing had
“blurred the lines between monetary and fiscal policy”.
The report states that although QE was undertaken as a monetary
policy decision, it had consequences for the management of public
debt, so I endorse the report's suggestion that the Bank and the
Debt Management Office
“should draw up and publish a memorandum of understanding which
clarifies how the interaction between monetary policy and debt
management should operate”.
With regard to the Bank's remit, I agree with the committee's
conclusion that it had been at risk of being asked to do too
much. It should not, as the report says, need to expand it to
government policy on climate change. I am completely supportive
of the report's view that giving the Bank's Monetary Policy
Committee and Financial Policy Committee multiple secondary
objectives to consider risks drawing the Bank
“into the Government's wider policy agenda”
and
“jeopardises the Bank's ability to prioritise price and financial
stability”,
which are the primary objectives of the MPC and FPC
respectively.
I will move on to the topic of diversity of thought. It is
interesting that the committee highlights evidence from witnesses
who suggested that a lack of “intellectual diversity” at the Bank
contributed to the misdiagnosis of inflation being transitory as
it rose from 2021. I approve of the recommendation that
“it is imperative that its membership comprises people of
different backgrounds and economic perspectives. The Bank must be
pro-active in encouraging a diversity of views and a culture of
challenge. This should be reflected in its hiring practices and
its appointment procedures”.
I highlight the committee questioning that HM Treasury leads the
process for appointing members of the MPC and that many of the
appointees have a Treasury background, which
“does not strengthen the perception of independence”.
I approve of the recommendation that HM Treasury and the Bank's
Court of Directors commission an independent review of the
appointments process to consider how public appointments are
made, what best practice was for other central banks, and to
propose measures which ensure that the appointments process is
transparent.
Moving on to the subject of forecasting, the report also
highlights the role of inadequate modelling techniques in
misdiagnosing the rise in inflation. It suggested that this
error, made by other central banks as well as the Bank of
England, may have reflected a general reliance on dynamic
stochastic general equilibrium models. Witnesses argued that,
because these models assume that “inflation expectations” play a
significant role in determining inflation and that central banks
are assumed to be able to effectively influence those
expectations through their actions, they tend to predict that
inflation will return to its target role over the forecast
period. However, although these underlying assumptions may hold
in times of economic stability, witnesses suggested that they
were unlikely to be valid during periods of significant economic
change, leading central banks to underestimate the strength and
persistence of inflationary episodes.
Turning to the subject of accountability, I do not agree with the
report's recommendation that the Bank's actions should be
regularly scrutinised by Parliament. The danger of this is that
short-termism could re-emerge in its actions. However, I am
content with the proposal that
“Parliament conducts an overarching review, supported by expert
staff, of the Bank's remit, operations and performance”
every five years.
The Bank of England's response of February to the report is very
disappointing. The governor, Andrew Bailey, seems to brush aside
most criticism or advice, except emphasising that the Bank does
focus on its primary objectives.
The Government's response contained two interesting reactions.
The Chancellor said that monetary policy and debt management
“remain distinct areas with separate mandates, responsibilities,
and decision-making processes”.
He said that the framework for debt management
“has not changed as a result of developments in monetary
policy”
over recent years, such as the introduction of QE. However, he
noted that the Government and the Bank were “mindful” of the
potential for quantitative tightening to interfere with the debt
issuance programme conducted by the Debt Management Office. He
noted that the Bank was liaising with the DMO to minimise this
risk, in line with a commitment made to the governor in a public
letter to the then Chancellor in 2020. Secondly, the Government
seem to have taken on board the report's recommendation that the
Bank should not need to focus on subjects such as climate
change.
I now move on to the review by Dr Bernanke of the Bank's forecast
process. The review found that the accuracy of the Bank's
economic forecast had
“deteriorated significantly in the past few years”
and noted that
“forecasting performance has worsened to a comparable degree in
other central banks and among other UK forecasters”
over the same period.
The review made criticisms in three areas. First, it found that
some of the Bank's key forecasting software was
“out of date and lacks important functionality”.
Secondly, Bernanke suggested that the Bank relied on human
judgment to
“paper over problems with the models”,
given the Bank's bias towards
“making incremental changes in successive forecasts”.
He argued that such an approach was slowing
“recognition of important structural changes in the economy”.
Thirdly, he said that the Bank relied too much on its central
economic forecast in communicating its outlook and policy
decisions to the public. Fourthly, and most importantly, he
recommended that the use of
“fan charts to convey the range of uncertainty”
in the central forecast should be dropped. We await the response
of the governor to the review.
Finally, these are my thoughts on what is not in the report and
is overlooked by the review. I am afraid that the MPC and the
governor were asleep at the wheel. At the Society of Professional
Economists dinner in September 2021, when inflation was at nearly
double its target, the governor said in his speech that the rise
was transitory. I note the special circumstances of Covid and the
Ukraine war, but why did the MPC not consult the regional offices
to see what was going on on the ground? I was doing a building
project at the time and suddenly realised that the cost of
bricks, plaster, glass and render was rising in an extraordinary
way and they were difficult to get hold of. While I am not an
economist, I feel that QE was kept on for too long. As many noble
Lords have said, the governor should have paid more attention to
the money supply increase that presaged the major inflationary
climb in the late 1980s and raised interest rates earlier, which
would have limited the rise in inflation.
2.27pm
(LD)
My Lords, first, I congratulate the noble Lord, of Chelsea, on his maiden
speech. He speaks with great expertise. I suspect that
occasionally we will agree, but frequently we will disagree, but
that is the purpose of the House.
I was privileged to be on the Economic Affairs Committee when it
developed the report and so this is my opportunity to thank our
chair, the noble Lord, of Headley, for his
outstanding leadership on this and other issues. I miss
participating in the EAC.
I will speak later about accountability and the lessons that we
have to learn that are embedded in this report and the Bernanke
report. But to my surprise, I think it is very important that I
first state clearly and unwaveringly the support of my party for
an operationally independent Bank of England. It seems to me that
in the debate today that has been called into question—along a
spectrum, perhaps with the noble Lords, and , at the more extreme end—but
it is crucial if we are to have credibility in domestic and
international public markets and with the public at large. If
there is one body that the public mistrusts more than the Bank of
England, it is certainly politicians. I thank the noble Lord,
Lord King, for giving us in great detail examples of how it is
just impossible for anyone at a senior level in politics not to
seek to manipulate issues such as interest rates and inflation
when there is electoral and political victory at stake.
As I said, the report contains many recommendations that I hope
will be taken up. The one that captures me the most, and this was
picked up by virtually every speaker, is the issue of groupthink.
The noble Earl, Lord Effingham, quoted Ben Bernanke, whose
observation that the Bank's
“deficiencies were characteristic of the central banking
community in general rather than the Bank alone”
speaks to the broad groupthink that affected the whole central
banking community globally.
I fully endorse the recommendations in our report for more
diversity of thought at the Bank and the proposal that the Court
of the Bank should play a stronger oversight role. Back in 2016 I
opposed the Government's decision to reduce the number of
non-executives on the court and abolish its oversight committee.
It is now vital that challenge be brought back into the system,
at both court and monetary policy level. I will talk about
accountability later, but the element of challenge is vital. It
is just improbable that people of sufficient calibre and
expertise, across a variety of thought, cannot be recruited into
the various and appropriate bodies within the committees of the
Bank.
I turn to the Bernanke report. Like the noble Baroness, Lady
Liddell—and the noble Lord, , may have said the same thing—I
was shocked to realise just how out of date the tools are that
underpin economic forecasting at the Bank. For those who have not
read the report, the phrases include:
“Some key software is out of date and lacks functionality …
insufficient resources … makeshift fixes … unwieldy system”.
That is really quite damning. How we got here I do not know, but
I suspect that everyone in the House would agree that it needs to
be changed quickly, and the noble Baroness, Lady Lane-Fox, is
certainly someone I would turn to for advice in this arena.
Once we got a grip on the fact that the forecasting is inadequate
at present, I began to have some understanding of why neither the
Bank nor the Treasury seems to capture and understand the risks
of continuous quantitative easing, including the fiscal
implications of, in effect, swapping nearly half the public debt
overnight from long-term fixed rates to volatile rates, halving
duration and aggravating asset inflation. We have to recognise
that quantitative easing was a vital tool in dealing with
liquidity problems, certainly after the 2008 crash and in the
early days of Covid, but it is not an elixir to drive forward
economic growth. That issue should have been caught if we had had
much better forecasting and ranges of scenarios as well as
diversity of thinking.
We now face quantitative tightening at a time when the Treasury
is also issuing high levels of public debt and one of the major
purchasers of gilts, the DB pension funds, have far less appetite
for those instruments. We are in a difficult place, and it is
going to take some time to unwind all this. I go back to the
argument that these issues need to be resolved by the Bank
objectively looking at the economy, not by political
interference.
As well as fixing the system at the Bank, we have to ensure that
the Treasury and the Bank can at least communicate properly with
each other, without compromising the Bank's independence, to
ensure that fiscal policy and monetary policy are made with an
understanding of what is happening in each arena. As our report
says, that co-ordination responsibility falls primarily with the
Government; they set the inflation target for the Bank and
control fiscal policy. However, as we took evidence, I could not
see any clear lines of responsibility or clear communication
mechanisms. It seems to me that the issue is handled largely
informally, and I think we would all ask for more clarity. I
strongly endorse the report's recommendation that the Bank and
the Debt Management Office of HM Treasury should publish an MoU
on the interaction between monetary policy and debt management.
Like the many others who have said this, I simply do not
understand why the Treasury does not publish the deed of
indemnity—that is completely beyond me.
Our report—this is where I probably differ from some others on
the committee—focuses quite strongly on the remit of the Bank,
which has of course expanded significantly in recent years, and
recommends far more transparency and debate around that remit,
especially in Parliament. I agree with that process of debate and
transparency, but I think this issue is getting seriously
overplayed. Staff and resource the Bank properly and, it seems to
me, it can cope with more than a single remit. In terms of
shaping our economy to tackle climate change, I would be very
worried to see the Bank of England step out of that arena in the
crisis that we face.
Let me close on the issue of the accountability of a body as
central as the Bank is to the functioning of our economy.
Independence is not in conflict with accountability; for that
reason, I believe that aspects of the work of the Bank should be
looked at by our new Financial Services Regulation Committee.
That committee is a significant step forward, but the Bank could
make that work, and parliamentary scrutiny, easier if it
effectively ensured a flow of information to us. Information
seems to come out in unquestioned bites or has to be extracted
through very brief committee evidence sessions. I would like to
see a much more open and constant flow of information. For
example, in the case of quantitative easing, it could have helped
Parliament greatly had we had a detailed discussion of the
economic risks from significantly expanding the Bank's balance
sheet. To do that, we have to have a committee that is properly
resourced and powerful.
I very much agree with the noble Lord, , that Parliament has a
responsibility, as a whole, to step up its level of oversight. I
hope we will seize on that. I hope indeed that the Government,
and all sides of this House, will provide support to the proposal
from the noble Lord, , and the committee that we
have a detailed five-year review, so that this discussion is
regularly in front of us. Also, there should be no no-go areas.
Why should we not discuss issues such as the inflation target?
Discussion and challenge are very different from political
interference and taking over control. Because we know that there
has been a failure to provide diversity in appointments, it also
seems to me that somehow bringing Parliament into some element of
a confirmation process makes a great deal of sense.
I believe that there is a lot we can do and lessons that we can
learn. I very much endorse the support of the committee and I am
pleased we have got the Bernanke report. I wish it was all being
taken a bit more seriously by both the Bank and the Government.
Again, I thank the committee for the privilege of allowing me to
have been one of its members.
2.37pm
(Lab)
My Lords, I congratulate the noble Lord, of Headley, on his opening
speech. I thank him and the Economic Affairs Committee for their
report into an independent Bank of England. It is a pleasure to
speak in such an illustrious debate today, alongside so many
distinguished and genuinely expert noble Lords. It was a
particular pleasure to listen to the noble Lord, of Lerwick, whose reforms as
Chancellor laid some of the groundwork for independence. I join
others in also congratulating the noble Lord, of Chelsea, on his maiden
speech.
This report from the Economic Affairs Committee marks the 25th
anniversary of Bank of England independence, which the committee
described as an appropriate time to review the operation of the
framework first set out in the Bank of England Act 1998, taken
through the House of Commons—as her excellent speech reminded
us—by my noble friend Lady Liddell of Coatdyke. I consider it a
privilege to have worked in the Treasury for the Chancellor who
introduced operational independence with respect to monetary
policy. The committee quotes Gordon Brown's reasoning for this
move:
“we will only build a fully credible framework for monetary
policy if the long-term needs of the economy, not short-term
political considerations, guide monetary decision-making. We must
remove the suspicion that short-term party-political
considerations are influencing the setting of interest
rates”.
Those words, as the noble Lord, Lord King, made clear, have
proved to be correct.
As a result, there is now a broad consensus in favour of
retaining independence, and it has become one of the most
enduring reforms of the new Labour Government. Indeed, in the
Government's response to this report, the current Chancellor
stated that he remains
“fully committed to monetary policy independence”.
The committee's report bears out this consensus, while rightly
acknowledging that external factors, such as globalisation, have
contributed to favourable conditions over this period. The report
states:
“For much of the past 25 years, the enhanced credibility of
monetary policy brought about by independence has contributed to
a low inflation environment. The absence of political
interference is seen by many as a major component of stable
inflation expectations”.
The report also confirms that the majority of expert witnesses
who gave evidence to the inquiry were clear that independence has
been a significant factor in promoting price stability. I am
therefore pleased the committee concluded it has a
“strong view that independence should be preserved”.
I regret, however, that this view was not shared by all former
Prime Ministers. , who is currently on a book tour, stated in an
interview with LBC radio on 15 of April, that interest rate
setting is “a political decision” that
“should be in political hands”.
In a world of unparalleled complexity and uncertainty, it is
institutions which can provide the stability of direction,
co-ordination and appropriate incentives for sustained economic
success. For much of our history, the strength of our
institutions has bestowed credibility in international markets
and underpinned our economic success. Politicians who undermine
those strengths play a dangerous game.
As the noble Lord, , said, we saw the consequences
of exactly that in the aftermath of the disastrous mini-Budget in
September 2022, with its programme of unfunded tax cuts, amidst a
concerted effort to undermine our independent economic
institutions. Markets spiralled, the pension fund industry came
close to collapse, and the Bank of England had to step in to
restore calm. Those events dramatically altered the economic
fortunes of our country. In October 2021, the Bank of England
base rate stood at 0.1%. In little over two years, that rose to
5.25%. In October 2021, debt interest was forecast to cost £29
billion this year; that figure now stands at £82 billion.
The last Labour Government introduced Bank of England
independence, and the next Labour Government will maintain it. It
is Labour's view that the Bank's Monetary Policy Committee must
continue to have complete independence in the pursuit of its
primary objective of price stability. A Labour Government would
retain the 2% inflation target, while the Financial Policy
Committee will continue with its core objective of financial
stability.
The Economic Affairs Committee's report raises a number of key
issues, which it believes need to be addressed. The first of
these concerns the interaction between fiscal and monetary
policy, where the committee believes clear lines of
responsibility and effective communication are required between
the Bank and the Treasury. I note that the Bank of England Act
sets out that, subject to the Bank's objectives to maintain price
and financial stability, the Bank should support the economic
policy of His Majesty's Government, including their objectives
for growth and employment.
With respect to fiscal policy, Bank of England independence
reflected an understanding that politics will always present a
powerful temptation to pursue macroeconomic policies that may not
be in the medium to long-term national economic interest. Similar
logic applies to the concept of deficit bias. Politicians may be
tempted to put off necessary fiscal decisions or to ignore the
long-term consequences of policy choices. It remains true, as
said, that in a modern
economy
“the discretion necessary for effective economic policy is
possible only within a framework that commands market credibility
and public trust”.
That is especially true if the Government are to be able to take
urgent, discretionary action when crisis strikes.
Far from wanting to “see the back of” the Office for Budget
Responsibility, as some now advocate, the next Labour Government
will strengthen the OBR with a new fiscal lock, guaranteeing in
law that any Government making significant and permanent tax and
spending changes will be subject to an independent forecast from
the OBR. We will not waver from strong fiscal rules. In line with
the committee's call for accountability to Parliament, the new
fiscal lock and fiscal rules will be put to Parliament to
agree.
The second issue identified by the committee's report concerns
the Bank's remit, an issue raised by many noble Lords today. The
committee believes that the widening of the remit to include
climate change, for example, risks jeopardising the Bank's
ability to prioritise its primary objectives. I respectfully
disagree. Monetary policy and financial regulation cannot stand
still in the face of new risks, not least those posed by climate
change. The European Central Bank's Isabel Schnabel has set out
the implications of climate change for monetary policy: losses
that could translate into the balance sheets of financial
institutions and reduce the flow of credit; impacts on labour
productivity and health-related inactivity, which could lower the
equilibrium real rate of interest and constrain the space for
conventional monetary policy; and the impact of supply-side
shocks on prices. Given the onus to mobilise investment to
achieve the energy transition, those challenges are especially
acute.
As the noble Baroness, Lady Lane-Fox of Soho, said, macroeconomic
policy has an important role to play in our climate transition.
Labour has set out plans to require financial institutions and
FTSE 100 companies to publish their carbon footprints and adopt
credible 1.5 degrees-aligned net-zero plans. We disagree with the
current Chancellor's decision to downgrade the emphasis put on
climate change in the remits of both Bank committees. The next
Labour Government will reverse these changes at the first
opportunity, because there can be no durable plan for economic
stability, and no sustainable plan for economic growth, that is
not also a serious plan for net zero.
The committee's inquiry also examined the possible introduction
of a central bank digital currency. Here, Labour recognises the
growing case for a state-backed digital pound to protect the
integrity and sovereignty of the Bank of England and the UK's
financial and monetary system. We fully support the Bank of
England's work in this area. The committee's report rightly
raises a number of public policy issues that could arise,
including issues such as threats to privacy, financial inclusion
and stability, which we too want to ensure are effectively
mitigated in the design of any such digital currency.
The final issue raised by the committee's report is
accountability, referred to by several noble Lords, including my
noble friend and the noble Lord, of Earl's Court. I very
much welcome the Chancellor's commitment, in his response to this
report, to send copies of remit letters to the chairs of your
Lordships' Economic Affairs Committee and the Treasury
Committee.
I again thank the noble Lord, of Headley, and the Economic
Affairs Committee for their report. Throughout this debate, we
have heard about the damage that inflation can do to family
finances. The Bank of England therefore plays a crucial role in
our nation's economy. Some 25 years since independence, this
report provides a valuable basis for debate.
2.47pm
The Parliamentary Secretary, HM Treasury () (Con)
My Lords, what an outstanding debate. I particularly thank my
noble friend for so skilfully opening it,
and the Economic Affairs Committee. So many of its members have
spoken today, and I thank them for their contributions, for the
thoughtful and detailed way in which they carried out the inquiry
and the report on the Bank of England, and for the breadth of
witnesses they chose to interview. I am delighted that my noble
friend of Chelsea chose a Treasury
debate in which to make his maiden speech—of course, I am not
surprised. He will make a great contribution to your Lordships'
House for many years to come, and we look forward to it.
Price stability is essential for a strong economy and,
consequently, strong public finances. It is widely recognised
that an operationally independent central bank is the best way to
achieve price stability. That is why the UK enshrines the Bank of
England's operational independence in law, with price stability
as the primary objective of the Bank's Monetary Policy Committee.
The Treasury and the Government remain committed to not only
independence but the objective of price stability, and I am
delighted that I therefore agree wholeheartedly with the noble
Baroness, Lady Kramer, and the noble Lord, Lord Livermore—not a
frequent occurrence in my life—with both Front Benches also
wishing to retain the independence of the Bank of England.
My right honourable friend the Chancellor wrote to the chair of
the EAC in January this year. It is worth briefly summarising
some of the commitments that he made in his letter. At the outset
he noted the operationally independent monetary policy, which is
so important within the broader macroeconomic framework, and
indeed the importance of the separation of fiscal and monetary
policy in the effective delivery of monetary policy. The
Chancellor noted the negative impacts of inflation on so many
elements of society and our economy when it is greater or lower
than 2%, and he again resolved not to change the definition of
price stability. This aligns with the view of the EAC, but it
should also be noted that the Federal Reserve and the European
Central Bank have the same inflation targets. The Chancellor also
noted the Government's previous review of the monetary policy
framework in 2013, which drew the same conclusions.
The Chancellor went on to note the Government's commitment to
ensuring that fiscal and monetary policy remain aligned to
support the Bank's efforts to return inflation sustainably to 2%.
This is in agreement with the conclusions of the committee. This
has meant reducing the level of government borrowing in a way
that gradually withdraws support from the economy, as
demonstrated by the declining path for the cyclically adjusted
primary deficit.
On the relationship between the Bank and the Debt Management
Office—the DMO, which many noble Lords have mentioned today—the
Chancellor noted that monetary policy and debt management are
distinct areas with separate mandates and decision-making
processes. Given the institutional separation of monetary and
debt management policy, in addition to existing public documents
clarifying the relevant governance structure, the Government do
not consider that an additional memorandum of understanding
between the two organisations is necessary to clarify their
relationship further.
On the committee's call—and indeed that of many noble Lords,
including the noble Baroness, Lady Liddell, and the noble
Viscount, Lord Chandos—for the Government to publish the deed of
indemnity, the Chancellor reiterated in his response that the
Government would not. The deed contains operationally sensitive
information relating to government cash management practices. It
is not government practice to release information of this kind,
and nor is it in the public interest. However, crucially, the
Government are confident that this does not undermine the
transparency of these arrangements, given the publication of
other relevant reports and accounts, in addition to public
comment and costings from the Office for Budget Responsibility,
or OBR, on this topic.
of Headley (Con)
Can my noble friend explain why, then, the Governor of the Bank
of England told our committee that the publication of the deed of
indemnity would not excite people?
(Con)
I cannot comment on what the Governor of the Bank of England
thinks other people will think about a document that has not been
published. If I can get any more information, or encourage the
Bank of England to provide more clarity on that, I will—but it
remains the position of the Government, and indeed the Chancellor
in his response to the committee, that the document will not be
published.
I turn to the remits of the Monetary and Financial Policy
Committees, which also attracted an enormous amount of attention
during the debate. I will come on to them further after this
opening section on the Chancellor's views in response to the
committee. The secondary objectives are clearly framed as being
subject to the delivery of their primary objectives of price and
financial stability. However, the Government have taken steps to
simplify and clarify the FPC's remit to make sure that its role
in supporting the Government's economic policy is absolutely
clear.
I heard what the noble Lord, , said about his party
wanting to expand the remit letters once again. I believe that
would be unhelpful. I will go on to state exactly why climate
remains within the remit letters and the rationale for that. I
believe that greater clarity is essential and is something that
the Government will continue to focus on in future remit
letters.
The report recommends that the Bank's management structure be
streamlined; however, the Chancellor affirmed that the current
structure is appropriate. Finally, on the committee report's
recommendation that the Treasury and the Bank commission an
independent review of appointments to the Bank, the Chancellor
noted that the Government have no plans to commission such a
review. However, he did highlight the Treasury's interventions in
relation to ensuring diversity, in its broadest sense, in public
appointments.
As part of our support for the principle of the Bank's
independence, the Government do not comment on the conduct or
effectiveness of monetary policy, but I reassure all noble Lords
that I welcome the many insights I have heard today with regard
to monetary policy and the Bank's performance relating to it. I
am sure that those who are responsible for monetary policy and
the operation of the Bank of England will reflect on them,
too—but I will go no further in my response.
It is the case that we have been living through a period of high
inflation. It is too high. In the 20 years prior to independence,
inflation averaged over 6%: in the 20 years subsequent to
independence, inflation averaged closer to 2% and certainly
volatility also declined. But, since May 2021, we have seen a
period of particularly high inflation and I am very pleased that,
due to the actions of the Bank of England, supported by the
Government, it was at 3.2% in March.
I will now elaborate on a few key areas that I believe almost all
contributors to the debate focused on: the MPC/FPC remit letters;
appointments to the Bank of England; the accountability of the
Bank of England; and forecasting. On other matters, I will
probably write, because time is always the enemy of the Minister
at the Dispatch Box.
Returning to the issue of the FPC and MPC remit letters, which
was mentioned at the outset by my noble friend , but also by my noble friend
, both the MPC and FPC have
complex roles—that is clear—and it is right that their remits
reflect this complexity. But that does not necessarily mean that
the remits therefore have to be complex in themselves. It is
important that the committees' secondary objectives, on
supporting this Government's economic strategy, are clearly
defined, so that they are achievable. Clearly defining secondary
objectives does not detract from the hierarchy of objectives for
either committee, where the secondary objectives are framed as
being subject to the primary objectives of price or financial
stability. Moreover, the remit letters provide guidance on how
the committees should consider instances where there are
trade-offs between their objectives and how their assessment of
any trade-offs should be publicly communicated so that they can
be scrutinised.
The changes introduced in the 2023 FPC remit letter have improved
its clarity and focus, with clearer relevance to the FPC's
specific responsibilities and toolkit. It is more streamlined. I
accept that it is not as streamlined as many noble Lords would
like, but it is 20% shorter compared with that in 2022. There is,
of course, a balance to be struck. For example, it is important
that home ownership is listed as a priority, so that the FPC is
mindful of wider public policy aims when it is considering policy
relating to the mortgage market. A further example is climate
change, mentioned of course by the noble Baroness, Lady Bennett,
but also by many other noble Lords. It is widely accepted that
climate change poses systemic risks to the financial system. As
such, the remit continues to emphasise the relevance of climate
change to the primary financial stability objective. Delivering
net zero is also referenced as a key component of the
Government's economic policy, which the committee has a secondary
objective to support.
It is also important to consider the changes to the remit letter
in the context of the Government's wider work to ensure that the
regulators are considering the impacts of climate change. For
example, through the Financial Services and Markets Act 2023,
both the Financial Conduct Authority and the Prudential
Regulation Authority are required to have regard to the need to
contribute, where relevant, to the Government's progress towards
complying with the Climate Change Act 2008 and the Environment
Act 2021.
The climate and environmental components of this apply from
August 2023 and January 2025 respectively. So it is not the case
that, somehow, climate has been downgraded. The wording has
changed but the legal obligation to get to our net-zero targets
remains, and we must ensure that the financial system gets
there—and that includes the Bank of England. However, the primary
objectives of the two committees are very well set out in the
remit letter.
In the MPC remit letter, the primary objective, set out in law,
is maintaining price stability, defined as a 2% inflation target.
The MPC's remit includes the goal of increasing long-term energy
security and delivering net zero. If that is not clear, I am not
sure what would be. Specifying the Government's economic strategy
gives the Bank's policy committees important information on the
broader economic policy landscape, given their role in the UK's
macroeconomic framework.
Turning to appointments to the Bank of England and then to
accountability, the Government recognise that, to be effective,
public bodies need to have the broadest possible mix of skills,
experience and backgrounds: diversity in its broadest sense. All
appointments are made on merit and follow a fair and open
competition process.
The Treasury has taken steps to ensure that a diverse range of
candidates are considered for appointments to the Bank of
England. To do this, the Treasury promotes vacancies to a wide
group of people and, to improve the reach of an advert or
opportunity, sometimes uses recruitment consultants.
The Government believe that there is a diversity of thought on
the MPC and FPC, although the skill of hindsight remains elusive.
The Governor of the Bank of England recently said that, in the
last two years, about 25% of the MPC's meetings have had a split
vote among the executive members. I suggest that this
demonstrates the intellectual and analytical diversity requested
by my noble friends and of course Lord Effingham.
The Governor noted that there is a larger proportion of external
members of the Bank of England than in other central banks around
the world. While the FPC makes decisions by consensus, the
diversity of views expressed in the committee's meetings is
captured in published records.
As I have noted, the Bank of England has a unique arrangement
compared with other central banks, as it has internal members and
a greater proportion of external members on its policy
committees. The external members are appointed by the Chancellor,
and internal members who are on the Court of the Bank of England
are Crown appointments.
Focusing on the MPC, each member has expertise in the field of
economics and monetary policy. Members are independent and do not
represent particular groups or interests. The MPC's decisions are
made on the basis of one person, one vote, and each member of the
committee votes in a way that he or she believes is consistent
with the MPC's remit. A non-voting representative from the
Treasury also attends the committee's policy meetings.
The Chancellor is assisted in his decision-making on appointments
by advisory assessment panels, which include internal members
from the Treasury and the Bank, but also an independent external
panel member. It is for the Chancellor to choose the person they
wish to appoint and make a recommendation to the Prime Minister.
The Treasury is committed to enabling proper parliamentary
scrutiny of the appointments that it makes to public bodies,
which is a valuable and important part of the process. The
Treasury Select Committee conducts pre-commencement hearings
before a successful candidate is appointed to the Bank to start
their role.
All noble Lords—far too many to namecheck—have spoken about the
accountability of the Bank of England. It is worth discussing
this in further detail now, and I am sure there will be
opportunities to do so again in the future. I am particularly
grateful for the forensic opening remarks of my noble friend
, and of course for the
reflections of the noble Lord, , who sits on the Court
although speaks today in a personal capacity.
The Bank is held to account both by Parliament and by the
Treasury. A key role of the Treasury and elected Treasury
Ministers is to legislate for and maintain the overall regulatory
architecture in a way that allows the Bank to meet its
objectives. There are many ways in which Parliament, stakeholders
and the public can scrutinise the performance of the Bank of
England. Key publications include the Bank's Financial Stability
Reports, which are published biannually, and the Monetary Policy
Reports, which are published quarterly. Indeed, a Monetary Policy
Report is due to be published this time next week. Executive and
external members of both the MPC and FPC typically appear before
the Treasury Select Committee following the publication of those
reports. The governor also appears in front of the EAC, as he did
in February this year.
The Government implemented reforms through the Bank of England
and Financial Services Act 2016 to increase the accountability of
the Bank and to improve the scrutiny of the Bank in terms of
financial stability. Those reforms were made once the expansions
in the Bank's remit had time to bed in properly after the
financial crisis. Measures introduced in the 2016 Act included
making the FPC a full policy committee of the Bank and creating a
clear accountability line to the Bank's Court of Directors. It
also implemented the recommendations of the Warsh review,
published in 2014, including to increase the transparency of the
MPC's decision-making by publishing a detailed policy statement
as soon as practicable after each policy meeting.
The Bank's remit letters were commented on frequently in today's
debate. They are published online and laid before Parliament,
typically as part of a fiscal event. After a fiscal event,
parliamentarians have the opportunity to debate it—it happens in
your Lordships' House and in the House of Commons.
Parliamentarians can and do raise concerns about the remit
letters during those debates. The issues are then considered as
part of the process to update the remit letter the following
year. Parliamentary committees offer further scrutiny of the
remits by calling bank executives, committee members and
government Ministers to appear before them—the EAC's inquiry is
an excellent example of parliamentary scrutiny in action. Given
the frequency with which the remits are updated and that there is
the opportunity to provide input, the Government do not intend to
publish draft letters. However, on many of the report's other
recommendations on accountability, it is for Parliament to decide
whether to conduct a review of the remit, and indeed the
operations of the Bank outside of existing processes, or to
create a standing committee.
The Treasury meets with the Bank of England regularly to discuss
its assessment of the economy and financial services. That
includes regular meetings between the Chancellor and the Governor
of the Bank of England. The Chancellor and governor are also
legally required to discuss the FPC's Financial Stability
Report.
Finally on accountability, the Court of Directors is a key
element for keeping the Bank's performance under review and for
looking at the way that the Bank exercises its statutory
functions.
I note that many noble Lords have made requests for the
Government to intervene in the operation of the Bank,
particularly on the allocation of resources. Obviously, the
Government will not do that to an independent Bank of England,
but I am confident that the suggestions and points raised in
today's debate may well be heard by those who are
responsible.
I have been given a one-minute warning, so I will try to speak on
forecasting and Bernanke within the time limit, because many
noble Lords raised this incredibly important issue. All of us who
have ever worked in finance—including me—know that forecasting is
sometimes a mug's game, but sometimes it can be incredibly
helpful. The review led by Dr Ben Bernanke is incredibly helpful
to highlight the areas in which the Bank needs to improve. I
think that the Bank is welcoming it, and I note that I will do a
full report on its response to the Bernanke review by the end of
the year.
As ever, I will write on many of the remaining points that I have
not been able to cover. I am again enormously grateful to my
noble friend and his committee for all
their contributions, not only to the report but to today's
debate. The Government will continue to support the independence
of the Bank of England and will ensure that its remit and the
framework in which it operates, including through fiscal policy,
create an environment in which it can carry out its duties
efficiently.
3.09pm
of Headley (Con)
My Lords, this has been an absolutely terrific debate and I thank
all speakers who have taken part. In particular, I congratulate
my noble friend of Chelsea on his maiden
speech, and I very much look forward to his further
contributions. In passing, I would like to congratulate the noble
Lord, Lord King, on moving from looking after the MPC to looking
after the MCC, where I am sure he will root out groupthink and
shoddy forecasting.
We covered an enormous amount of ground and your Lordships will
be delighted, given that I am sure everyone wants to get a very
late lunch, that I will not try to repeat it all. I will just
summarise what I have heard by saying that I can sense broad
consensus—I stress “broad”; there is not unanimity—on four key
points.
The first is about independence itself. It is clear from this
debate that the vast majority of speakers think that independence
should be preserved. Some have questioned its contribution more
than others, but as far as I can sense noble Lords think that
independence should be kept. On the framework for operational
independence, here I sense that there is a consensus that that
framework is, as our report stated, under quite considerable
strain. A number of noble Lords—the noble Lords, and , for example—spoke of the
blurring of the distinction between operational independence and
policy independence. A number of your Lordships referred to the
blurring of the lines between fiscal and monetary policy. Why has
this happened? Obviously, we debated that: the remit being
expanded, QE and QT and the enormous fiscal and economic impact
of that. Therefore, there seems to be consensus that there is
quite a significant challenge we need to face on the
framework.
The second area where there seems to be consensus is, pretty
obviously, that the Bank failed to control inflation in recent
years. Again, there was consensus on the need for much more focus
on intellectual diversity, not just forecasting—although my noble
friend made a very good speech on
that. We need to look at both people and process.
Area number three where I sense there is broad consensus—here I
stress “broad”—is about what should be done. Let us just try to
divide this up. There is performance: issues that need to be
tackled to improve performance. I do not think there is consensus
on the remit; I sense from noble Baronesses opposite that there
is opposition, obviously, to some of the points that were made in
our report. However, I stress—I will come back to this in a
moment—that those differing views highlight the need for much
more debate and scrutiny of the remit letter. That said, there is
consensus that a lot more needs to be done on the hiring and
appointment processes within the Bank, and again, for different
reasons. The noble Baroness, Lady Bennett, has a different view
to mine on this, but I think that we would all welcome that and,
again, more scrutiny and accountability are necessary there.
The next area where I sense there is consensus is the need for
more transparency and more clarity. I am sorry to have intervened
on my noble friend, but I am still completely baffled as to why
we cannot have the deed of indemnity published. It is an
absolutely critical document. Billions of pounds are at stake
here, and I find it very odd that we in Parliament cannot be told
the details around the deed of indemnity. I find it extraordinary
just simply to be told it is market sensitive when the governor
told our committee a very different thing. We will have to return
to that. Likewise, I think that there is a need for clarity on
debt management. I will not repeat the points there, but I want
to stress points made by my noble friends Lady Noakes and . It is important that, at
times, we take a step back and ask ourselves whether we are
absolutely clear as to where our responsibility for fiscal and
monetary policy lies. As I said, I think this framework is being
challenged. We should not see it as pickled in aspic. We should
be courageous enough to ask questions about it, as the noble
Baroness, Lady Kramer, said. Challenge strengthens
independence.
Finally, therefore, I think that there is broad consensus on the
need for Parliament to up its game. Indeed, this debate, lasting
three hours, shows the value of constructive criticism and
challenge. I note what my noble friend said. Of course we need to be
mindful of the tightrope between independence and accountability,
and to be respectful of what operational independence means.
However, that is no reason to say that we should not up our
game.
Ahead of this debate, I asked the House of Lords Library to look
up how many debates have taken place in this Chamber and the
other place specifically on issues relating to the Bank's
performance. How many do we think there might have been over the
last five years—10? There has been one in this House on QE, one
Private Notice Question and none in the other place. I completely
agree with what my noble friend said. There are opportunities for
parliamentarians to question the operational framework of the
Bank, the remit letters and so on. We are delighted to welcome
the Governor of the Bank and the Chancellor to the Treasury
Committee—or, in our case, the Economic Affairs Committee—but
given the magnitude of the topics that we have been discussing
today, enormous issues such as climate change and QE, is that
really enough?
We may differ on the role and remit of the Bank, or on monetary
policy, but surely we all agree that if we are giving these
enormous powers to unelected officials, we need more
transparency, more scrutiny, more accountability and more action
in Parliament. Overall, reform is needed.
Motion agreed.
|