Draft Renewables Obligation (Amendment) Order 2018 The
Committee consisted of the following Members: Chair: Phil Wilson †
Cadbury, Ruth (Brentford and Isleworth) (Lab) † Charalambous,
Bambos (Enfield, Southgate) (Lab) † Creasy, Stella (Walthamstow)
(Lab/Co-op) † Drax, Richard (South Dorset) (Con) † Francois, Mr
Mark (Rayleigh and Wickford) (Con) † Grant, Mrs Helen (Maidstone
and The Weald) (Con) † Harris, Rebecca (Lord Commissioner...Request free trial
Draft Renewables Obligation (Amendment) Order 2018
The Committee consisted of the following Members:
Chair:
† Cadbury, Ruth (Brentford and Isleworth) (Lab)
† Charalambous, Bambos (Enfield, Southgate) (Lab)
† Creasy, Stella (Walthamstow) (Lab/Co-op)
† Drax, Richard (South Dorset) (Con)
† Francois, Mr Mark (Rayleigh and Wickford) (Con)
† Grant, Mrs Helen (Maidstone and The Weald) (Con)
† Harris, Rebecca (Lord Commissioner of Her Majesty’s Treasury)
Hoey, Kate (Vauxhall) (Lab)
† Mak, Alan (Havant) (Con)
† Moore, Damien (Southport) (Con)
† O’Brien, Neil (Harborough) (Con)
† Perkins, Toby (Chesterfield) (Lab)
† Perry, Claire (Minister for Energy and Clean Growth)
Siddiq, Tulip (Hampstead and Kilburn) (Lab)
† Smith, Nick (Blaenau Gwent) (Lab)
† Swayne, Sir Desmond (New Forest West) (Con)
† Whitehead, Dr Alan (Southampton, Test) (Lab)
Nehal Bradley-Depani, Committee Clerk
† attended the Committee
Third Delegated Legislation Committee
Monday 2 July 2018
[Phil Wilson in the Chair]
Draft Renewables Obligation (Amendment) Order 2018
6.00 pm
-
The Minister for Energy and Clean Growth (Claire
Perry)
I beg to move,
That the Committee has considered the draft Renewables
Obligation (Amendment) Order 2018.
It is a pleasure to serve under your chairmanship on this
lovely sunny evening, Mr Wilson.
The draft order would amend the Renewables Obligation Order
2015, which, as the Committee knows, provided the detailed
legislative framework for the operation of the renewables
obligation scheme in England and Wales. The order is
designed to control the costs to consumers—something we all
care about—of supporting unexpected generation under the
renewables obligation from two types of generating station
defined in the legislation: biomass conversion stations and
co-firing stations.
Biomass conversion stations are former coal plants that
have converted to run wholly on biomass. Co-firing stations
combine a mixture of coal and biomass. The renewables
obligation scheme has been the main financial mechanism to
incentivise large-scale renewable electricity generation in
the UK. The scheme has now closed to new biomass, co-firing
and conversion projects, but existing projects will
continue to receive support up to 2027.
Of course, the scheme does not provide cash payments to
generators. It operates through a system of tradable
renewables obligation certificates. Electricity suppliers
have to present a certain number of certificates to Ofgem
to support each megawatt-hour of electricity they have
supplied to consumers. Ofgem issues RO certificates to
generators relative to the renewable electricity they
generate. Generators sell the certificates to energy
suppliers or to traders as tradable commodities. It is
assumed that the cost to electricity suppliers of complying
with the regulation is passed on to consumers through their
energy bills. The size of the obligation is set each year,
based on the number of certificates expected to be issued.
The RO scheme has been highly successful in bringing
forward renewable energy, and 25,000 stations across the UK
now generate more than 65 TWh of renewable electricity a
year, which is equivalent to about 22% of the UK
electricity supply market. As to its contribution to
decarbonisation, more than 28 million tonnes of carbon
dioxide emissions were avoided in 2016-17 alone. However,
we must of course keep energy bills as low as possible for
consumers while we go through the transition, and since
2015 steps have been taken to control costs; but we need to
do more.
It is our view that both co-firing and conversion stations
have an important transitional role to play in
decarbonising the grid, and they can generate at high
levels more or less continuously. However, stations already
accredited under the scheme can increase the amount of
biomass they use quickly and without notification to Ofgem,
which can, of course, significantly increase support costs.
The Government acted in 2014 to discourage that deployment
of new generating capacity by removing grandfathering
rights for certain sorts of co-firing and biomass
conversion generating stations. However, despite those
changes, last year evidence suggested that there was
significant unforecast generation, which is something we
are keen to avoid. Indeed, we think that if we were not to
intervene now, there would be an increase in bills of £2
per year per household. For business users, and
particularly those with low electricity consumption, there
would be increases of up to £140 per year, whereas the
bills of energy-intensive industries would increase by up
to £53,000 per year.
The reason the Committee is meeting tonight is to control
those costs by implementing annual caps on the number of
renewables obligation certificates that can be issued for
non-grandfathered biomass co-firing or conversion
generating stations or units. There are two sorts of
stations to which caps will apply: capped and mixed. Capped
stations comprise one or more capped combustion units only,
which are not protected by grandfathering policy. That
means, essentially, that there is a cap on the number of
certificates that can be issued to the station in each
obligation year, set at 125,000.
Mixed generating stations have both non-grandfathered
capped units, and exempt grandfathered units. The order
will set a flexible cap, first by estimating the number of
certificates likely to be issued for generation at the
exempt units. An allowance of 125,000 certificates will
then be added for each of the station’s capped units. If
generators choose to exceed their capped unit capacity,
further certificates will be issued for generation only up
to the level of the overall station caps. If generators
decide to maximise generation at their exempt grandfathered
units, there will be no restriction on the number of
certificates issued, provided that the capped units remain
within their allowance.
The order also makes some technical changes that are
unconnected to biomass conversion and co-firing. For
example, we are bringing certain combined heat and power
stations into line with the existing requirements for other
stations, and are requiring a declaration that double
subsidies will not be claimed under other schemes. The
order clarifies that existing greenhouse gas trajectories
in the Renewables Obligation Order 2015 apply equally to
electricity-only dedicated biomass power stations and
biomass power stations with combined heat and power. The
order will also clean up various typos, which do not have a
material effect on the legislation.
The Government are committed to keeping energy bills as low
as possible for consumers, while cutting greenhouse gas
emissions and supporting economic growth. The cap
mechanisms implemented through the order take into account
feedback from stakeholders. They balance the interests of
generators and consumers. The flexibility provided by this
approach will allow units to generate more when electricity
demand is highest. I commend the order to the Committee.
6.06 pm
-
(Southampton, Test)
(Lab)
It is a pleasure to serve under your chairmanship, Mr
Wilson.
As the Minister set out, the order essentially deals with a
very narrow point of policy relating to biomass conversions
and biomass production. It is about stations that have
converted from coal to biomass and are receiving renewables
obligation certificates—in other words, they converted
before the ROC period came to an end. As the Minister said,
there are no more stations in that category because,
although the ROC programme is continuing for another nine
years, it has been closed to new applicants since the
arrival of contracts for difference on 31 March 2017. The
order is about existing conversions that have an
expectation of the number of ROCs they would receive as a
result of their power generation. It contains a proposal to
limit the number of those ROCs. As the impact assessment
for the order states,
“The policy objectives are to protect the”
levy control framework
“and limit the costs to consumers of additional unforecast
RO spend on biomass conversion and co-firing.”
The Minister made a customarily comprehensive case about
the order’s purpose, but I am not sure it is likely to do
what is says on the tin. Will it really protect the LCF and
limit the costs to consumers of additional unforecast RO
expenditure, as described in the impact assessment, the
explanatory memorandum and the Minister’s statement? I ask
that question because the order is founded on renewables
obligation certificates, but it talks about the money
potentially spent or saved in relation to the levy control
framework. Those are not quite the same things, and I will
try to shed a little light on why.
Renewables obligation certificates came into place in 2002.
As we have mentioned, no new ROCs are issued now, but
during the period of their life, they were created as a
result of agreements that were set out with various
renewable power plants to provide a varying number of ROCs
per megawatt-hour of electricity produced. In that sense,
they are a little like bitcoin, inasmuch as they have been
mined, produced and then are in existence as a result of
the activity of producing energy, but they have no value in
themselves. They can obtain value as a result of being
bought, as the Minister said, by bodies that are obligated
by the ROC system to provide evidence that they have
supplied a proportion of their output from renewable power.
Such bodies can do that in two ways. First, they can show
at the settlement point a number of ROCs from their own
generating activity that coincides with their obligation
level—and if they do that, their obligation is met. On the
other hand, if they have a shortfall, or do not generate
any power from renewable sources, those suppliers would
have to meet their obligation via another route, in one of
two further ways. Either they pay a buyout price for their
ROC shortfall—the price will be administratively set by
Government at a substantially higher level than the likely
traded prices of ROCs—or they purchase from the companies
that have created the ROCs enough ROCs to meet their
obligation level.
That, of course, is what gives ROCs their value and places
money in the hands of the renewable generators who have
invested money in their projects with the expectation that,
in part, their project will be underwritten by the proceeds
of ROC sales. However, a question then arises: what is
likely to be the actual value of a ROC? It is that value
that is paid by the supplier and that impacts on customer
bills. It impacts on the levy control framework—that is, a
controlled total for the amount that can be spent on
underwriting for renewables over successive five-year
periods. It is not money that is actually spent, because it
is money that is effectively supplied by consumer bills. Of
course, that is real money as far as consumer bills are
concerned, but it is to be regarded as an imputed tax and
spend by the Treasury, so it is as if extra taxation had
been raised and then charged against the levy control
framework. That levy control framework is the subject of
the order, inasmuch as the Government’s imputed tax and
spend within that framework has been running ahead of what
that framework suggested it should be. Measures have
therefore been taken to try to get it within the overall
framework.
The next question that arises is whether the way in which
ROCs are valued is easily coterminous with what it is the
Government are trying to do about maintaining those levy
control framework levels. This is the key bit. If the value
of a ROC is high, that will result in more putative tax and
spend, and hence more cost against the levy control
framework. If the value is low, it results in some, but
less, cost against the levy control framework.
How does that value rise and fall? Essentially it comes
from two elements. First, there is the headroom that the
Government have built into the system. That is the level of
obligation suppliers have to meet. That is, or should be,
adjusted to remain ahead of the supplier ROCs so that they
retain value, and so that the generators are rewarded for
their efforts. The headroom sits in the system and will
have a central effect on ROCs’ values. That is, if the
headroom is set very high—10% above the current level of
the ROCs—then, with the obligation up to a relatively high
percentage of the power supplied by a supplier, the ROCs
will gain value, because people will chase more of them to
cover their obligation requirement. If the headroom is
reduced, the value of the ROCs drops. Furthermore, the more
ROCs in the system, even within the obligation level
framework, the easier it is for suppliers to obtain them to
meet their obligations. In other words, if more ROCs chase
a set amount of obligation space, the price will reduce.
How does that relate to what the draft statutory instrument
seeks to do? It wants to cap the number of ROCs for
particular plants operating biomass and bioliquid methods
of producing electricity. That retrospectively alters the
terms under which those companies undertook a build for
biomass or a conversion to biomass of a plant that
previously burned coal. Changing retrospectively the terms
of scheme is exactly what caused the 2015 hiatus when the
feed-in tariffs for solar were dropped. In this instance
the situation is worse, because although dropping those
FITs affected the development of new solar, it did not
affect the remuneration of existing plants. The draft order
seeks directly to affect the planned remuneration of
existing plants by shifting the goalposts after agreement
has been reached.
That is why a number of affected plants that had converted
from coal to biomass told the consultation that the changes
would make them—at least for the foreseeable future, and
presumably until the Government outlaw coal from the
system—produce electricity from coal and not from biomass,
since the terms of the altered system are such that it will
be economically less advantageous to generate power from
biomass and economically more advantageous, relatively
speaking, to produce power from coal, which I thought the
Secretary of State was against. Indeed, the Minister and I
have agreed considerably on the need to remove coal from
the system. It would be a particularly perverse outcome of
this instrument if we increased, rather than reduced, the
amount of coal being used to produce power in the system
over the next few years.
That, however, is the collateral damage, as it were, of a
less than perfect measure. The Government tell us that the
real effect of the cap on ROCs for those companies is that
it will take the pressure off the levy control framework.
The impact assessment explains at length just how much a
cap will save. It suggests that doing nothing means
expenditure of between £55 million and £320 million,
whereas under this draft instrument the range is between £5
million and £20 million.
It will not, however, necessarily do that. Capping the
number of ROCs that can be issued by plants would have a
potential effect on the number of ROCs available for
purchase. The effect would therefore be to increase the
value of the ROCs that will be available. The amount of
money paid out for them, which would be regarded as
putative tax and spend, would go back into the levy control
framework. That would not change the overall effect very
much, although that depends on the proportion of the total
amount of ROCs available and the plants affected, which the
impact assessment does not address.
The fine and detailed calculations made in the impact
assessment, which are in the SI and the explanatory
memorandum, do not add up to a hill of beans unless done
properly against what the countervailing effect of having
fewer ROCs in the system would do to the overall cost to
the levy control framework. I do not know what the exact
effect would be, but it does not appear to have been well
worked out. In principle, it possibly delivers the wrong
mechanism—saving costs to the levy control framework as far
as ROCs are concerned.
Far be it for me to advise the Government on what to do
about the ROCs system, which undeniably through its trading
mechanisms causes costs to consumers and the LCF total, but
in terms of a mechanism that would have an effect on those
costs it might be worth—
-
Will the hon. Gentleman accept an intervention that might
provide him with some comfort and save us a bit of time?
His suggestion is that if we had a totally free market with
an infinite number of ROCs and a price-setting mechanism
based on demand and supply, by capping the number of ROCs,
prices will go up and the overall value will be the same.
However, the obligation is set annually. Therefore, in
effect, every year a certain number of ROCs are issued,
taking into account that fewer ROCs in the system would
have an impact on that level. The ratchet will come down
based on there being fewer ROCs in the system. It is not a
completely dynamic system—there is that annual setting of
the absolute number.
-
Dr Whitehead
I thank the Minister for that intervention. Unfortunately,
the annual settlement for the amount of ROCs compared with
headroom took place last October.
-
It happens every year—now until 2027.
-
Dr Whitehead
Indeed, it happens every year, but the system will not
rectify itself in any way until about one and a half years
after the order is in place. Therefore, if ROCs are fewer
in number and increase in value, the workings carried out
may not have the effect that the Minister or the officials
who drew them up think they will have, because of how those
values relate to scarcity or abundance as far as possible
purchases are concerned.
I was going to mention, as the Minister did, the headroom
for ROCs. If one looked at the relationship of headroom to
the number of ROCs in circulation, one would certainly see
that having a depressing effect, but it would have a much
wider effect on the whole of the market. As a result of
our, I accept, quite lengthy expedition of how ROCs work,
work against each other and may or may not work up to the
levy control mechanism, does the Minister really think that
the order will work as she has described? Given the lack of
an assessment of a possible countervailing effect from a
reduction in ROCs because of how the system works, might it
not be a good idea to take that away and have another look
at it, to see whether it will work as well as she thinks
and whether any action on headroom figures might have an
equal effect, as I have just described? The countervailing
effects of the headroom recalculation might be worse than
the proposed measure.
I am not drawing any conclusions. I am stating that it does
not appear that all the factors relating to how ROCs work
have been taken into account in the calculations. I would
not like to see us pass legislation that does not do that
properly and that possibly draws us into areas where we
think we have done something about the system, but actually
we have done something rather different.
6.25 pm
-
I disagree with the hon. Gentleman. The information given
to me suggests that the set level of ROCs already factors
in cost control measures. The legislation cap takes into
account the ROCs that have been issued since April 2018.
The hon. Gentleman is proposing a “do nothing” scenario
where we would end up with higher bills and companies
continuing to receive unexpectedly high returns from
generation. We want to ensure that we achieve our
renewables targets, which we can do with the system and a
relentless focus on driving down consumer bills. We should
not be afraid to say that a system put in place for all the
right reasons has not delivered as we thought. Essentially,
people will always game whatever system is in place.
I take the hon. Gentleman’s point about ensuring that there
is not a policy hiatus, but there is none. We are proposing
a sensible change that will stop unexpected levels of
generation coming onstream, but the quid pro quo is that we
have given the generators flexibility in how they treat
their various plants. We have given them the ability to
have a bit of management within their own system.
I accept the estimates of the likely savings—I am sorry
that the hon. Gentleman does not, because my officials have
done an excellent job with the analysis—and the costs that
we will not see. It is an extra £1 or £2 for average
household bills, an extra £80 to £140 for business users,
and up to £53,000 for energy intensive industries, such as
steel, ceramics and cement, which he and I know are
extremely strategically important and have huge resonance
in many of our constituencies.
I am, as always, interested to listen to the hon.
Gentleman. I appreciate his detailed combing through of the
small print of every SI, but in this case I do not accept
that these numbers are wrong. I commend the order to the
Committee.
Question put.
Division 1
2 July 2018
The Committee divided:
Ayes: 9 Noes: 6 Ayes: 9 Noes: 6
Question accordingly agreed to.
|