John Penrose (Weston-super-Mare) (Con) I beg to move, That this
House has considered UK competition and consumer policy in response
to the Penrose review. It is good to have you looking after us, Mr
Efford, to ensure that we do not misbehave during the course of the
debate. It is good to see you in the Chair. Just over a year ago, I
was commissioned to write a report by the Treasury and the
Department for Business, Energy and Industrial Strategy. It came
out...Request free trial
(Weston-super-Mare) (Con)
I beg to move,
That this House has considered UK competition and consumer policy
in response to the Penrose review.
It is good to have you looking after us, Mr Efford, to ensure
that we do not misbehave during the course of the debate. It is
good to see you in the Chair.
Just over a year ago, I was commissioned to write a report by the
Treasury and the Department for Business, Energy and Industrial
Strategy. It came out almost exactly a year ago and it is called,
“Power To The People”. It is about competition policy and was
produced at the request of the Government. A year after
publication, I thought it was reasonably sensible to think that
we might want to have a look at what has happened as a result of
my recommendations—which ones have happened and which ones have
not—hoping perhaps to goad, tease or otherwise persuade my hon.
Friend the Minister to be as indiscreet as he possibly can be
about what might happen in future, to fill in any gaps, and
discuss the recommendations that have not yet taken place.
I will summarise briefly progress on implementing some of the
recommendations in the report in the intervening year and I will
focus fairly straightforwardly on the things that have not
happened yet, so that the Minister has a text from which to
work—if I may put it that way—and on the gaps that remain. To be
fair, although I do not want to overclaim on this, it is true to
say that there has been a reasonable amount of progress across
Government on some of the recommendations in my report.
For example, there have been a series of consultations and
commitments from the Competition and Markets Authority about the
kind of changes that it wants to make to its internal processes
and the way it works. One of the central recommendations in the
report is that the CMA needs stronger consumer powers—upgraded to
match its anti-trust competition powers—and a whole series of
other things necessary for it to move faster to judgments in
individual cases much more quickly. Ideally, in most cases—the
easier cases—that should be within days or months, rather than in
the current parlance, when things can easily run into years; we
need faster and more certain decisions.
The CMA is supposed to upgrade its capability to become what I
termed the “micro-economic sibling” to the Bank of England’s
macroeconomic work. In other words, every time the Bank of
England talks about the macro economy, the CMA should have a
public role in putting forward our progress in creating
supply-side reforms to improve competition in individual markets
and in individual parts of the country. As we all know, our
country has a real problem with declining levels of productivity
and of competitiveness the further away from the M25 one
travels.
The report therefore makes a series of recommendations, some
prompting a series of consultations on internal reforms to the
CMA, which are very welcome. There are things like the
“micro-economic sibling for the Bank of England”,
which I have just mentioned, which has been declared and is due
to be set up. There have also been declarations that the CMA’s
consumer powers will be upgraded in due course. We will need
primary legislation for that, but there has been extensive
consultation on it. There will also be things such as stronger
penalties for companies that do not comply with data requests and
so forth, seeking to slow down the progress of any competition
cases. So, all—or mostly—good news in that area at least.
The CMA has also established something called the digital markets
unit, the DMU, which will be absolutely essential to future
operations in ensuring that we can deal with consumer detriment
created by digital network monopolies—the big FANGs of Facebook,
Amazon, Netflix and Google. The DMU is now in operation, but in
shadow form, because it does not have any of the necessary
legislated powers that it requires. It has at least started.
There has also been an increase in the CMA’s resources post
Brexit because, as we left the UK, we had to have a stronger
domestic pro-competition set of institutions, otherwise all the
things that had been happening in Brussels, in the EU’s
competition world, would not have been coped with, so they were
repatriated.
Equally, the ideas in the chapter on economic regulators are
about trying to reduce the overall role of such regulators over
time. We should be trying to normalise as much of the markets
that they run as possible. There is no intrinsic reason why, for
example, energy, telecommunications or others cannot be mostly
normal and as usual, as run of the mill as buying a loaf of bread
or a pint of milk. We do not need an economic regulator to
protect us when we do that. There are large chunks of these
markets where we could be just as protected by normal consumer
protection laws, and would not need an economic regulator, except
for the bits of those markets that are fundamentally based around
network monopolies.
Every single one of the economically regulated sectors in our
economy—telecoms, energy, water or any of the others—all have
network monopolies at their core, whether it is electricity
distribution, the national grid, local electricity distribution
grids, gas pipes, water pipes or whatever it might be. There is a
network monopoly at the core, and those are inherently less
competitive. We cannot get them to work in the normal way, and
there has to be a residual level of economic regulation on those
networks. Perhaps there are some deeply embedded and
hard-to-solve consumer detriments in finance, too. Other than
that, we could and should seek to erode the role of the economic
regulators over time, normalising their markets as far as we can,
as this report recommends. It is not a quick process; it will
take time, but it can and should be done, outside the areas I
have just described.
How are we doing? In some respects, quite well. There is
something called the “Economic Regulation Policy Paper”, which I
am sure everybody here has been keeping next to their bed for
bedtime reading. That came out of the Department for Business,
Energy and Industrial Strategy a couple of weeks ago, and is
intended to address the statutory duties of the economic
regulators, and increase the level of competition they are
involved with. It makes all the right noises and speaks all the
right warm words about doing that. I will come back to that in a
minute, because one of its problems is that, in modernising the
statutory duties, to enable the process I have laid out, it is
going to
“launch a review of utilities regulators’ statutory duties in
2022.”
It does not say when that is going to be launched, when it will
be finished or what it will do about it when it is done.
Everybody here will be familiar with the term “long grass”. I
hope the Minister will be able to reassure us that this is not
long grass, that it will happen in a timely way, and that he is
out with his lawnmower trimming the sward to ensure that it will
happen, rather than get parked somewhere and gently
forgotten.
There is also good news on public procurement, which has been
brought into sharp focus during the pandemic. We absolutely need
to have a faster, better and more transparent public procurement
process. We inherited this process from the EU as the
OJEU—Official Journal of the European Union—rules. They do a lot
of good things, but incredibly slowly and in bureaucratic
fashion. As a result, we end up with processes that are clunky.
When we have a national or international emergency, such as the
pandemic, they are cruelly exposed as not working well
enough.
I am pleased to say that there was when I published this, and
there remains, a continuing commitment to launching a new public
procurement Bill. That is due, probably not in this Session, but
I hope in the next. It has been heavily trailed, and I hope and
expect that it will take what we have and make it much more
nimble, digital and open to small firms being able to compete
with long-standing large incumbents, such as Carillion. It will
not only be pro-competitive but will involve a great deal of
better value for money for taxpayers. It will mean that we are
less likely to have, for example, a scramble for personal
protective equipment, if we have another national emergency such
as the pandemic in future.
Finally, on the positive side of the ledger, there has been some
progress on the ideas I talked about for trying to improve
competition outside the south-east, and to improve retail
opportunities for people who need redress, if they have been done
wrong and their consumer rights have been breached. There has
been a little progress on trying to make small claims courts and
ombudsmen work better, more digitally and faster, while
continuing to be cheap, so that there is ready justice, if
necessary, for somebody who has not got what they paid for under
consumer rights. That is all good, but we have a great deal
further to travel.
My contention is that in a digital world, we should be able to
have the same kind of 24/7 service that we expect when logging on
to do our grocery shopping at 3 am— I do not do that, but some
people do. That is something that, increasingly, we expect to be
able to do. If we can shop 24/7, we should be able to seek
redress 24/7 when that is needed, but there is a noticeable gap
there.
Although that gap is starting to close, and there have been
reforms of the small claims court for example, there has been no
reform in other areas that need it, such as in the creation of
county competition courts. Such reform is necessary to create
opportunity for small, local companies that are being ganged up
on by larger local incumbents and prevented from prosecuting
their competition rights, because taking someone to the
Competition Appeal Tribunal in London for a breach of competition
law is never going to be affordable.
Even under the current fast-track approval process, redress is
still out of reach for most small regional firms. A restaurant in
Bristol, an estate agent in Hull or an hotelier in Liverpool will
not be able to afford to do anything if they are being ganged up
on by a local competitor until we get what I am calling “county
competition courts”. I am afraid that there has been little
progress towards that at the moment. Nor has there been progress
towards a generalised update and improvement of local trading
standards teams. That is needed in many parts of the country to
ensure that there are proper defenders of consumer rights.
I do not want to cavil too much, because there is a decent list
of progress. It would be churlish to say that nothing has
happened in the last year, because it really has. I commend the
Government and my hon. Friend the Minister on that progress, but
I am afraid that there is a slightly longer list—it is certainly
a serious list—of things that have not yet happened on the other
side of the ledger. I will run through them quickly, then leave
it for others to pick up on any particular points.
First, one of the report’s central points is about speeding up
how fast people can get justice through the CMA if they need it.
As I mentioned at the start of my speech, we have to ensure that
all but the most complicated, hideously difficult and
groundbreaking cases can be decided by the CMA. Most cases ought
to take weeks or months rather than years. At the moment, there
is no overall core process redesign within the CMA or the
Competition Appeal Tribunal, which is effectively the appeals
court for lots of CMA cases. Such a redesign—if I can call it
that—will be necessary to make dramatic improvements in the
availability and certainty of justice.
That matters because at the moment, it is all too easy for large,
well-lawyered incumbents to walk backwards, slowly, in the face
of a challenge from a small, plucky entrepreneurial, insurgent
firm that is trying to transform and disrupt a particular market.
If they can strew legal obstacles in the challenger’s path, they
can basically make it much harder for Britain’s economy to be
nimble.
(Truro and Falmouth)
(Con)
I appreciate what my hon. Friend says about competition. Does
that apply to local authorities, which tend just to employ one
arm’s length contractor when plenty of local people could bid for
jobs such as road building and maintenance, for example?
That is a particularly good example of the kind of problem that I
was referring to when I mentioned public procurement reforms. I
think we should be all extremely interested in what they show.
When those reforms come, they should mean that local government,
as well as national Government and many arm’s length bodies—from
the NHS to English Heritage, and everyone else in between—should
be able to make much faster decisions in a way that is more
accessible to small firms that are not equipped to wade through
pages and pages of tender documents, some of which require a PhD
and actually have little to do with whether a product or service
is better than the big incumbent’s. That will be an essential
change.
Speeding up the CMA is absolutely essential. One of the most
glaring and—I am afraid to say—saddest omissions from the
recommendations is on better regulation. There is a difference
between deregulation and better regulation. I am sure that you
are thoroughly familiar with it, Mr Efford, but for the record
and for everybody else, deregulation is where standards are got
rid of and there is a sort of race to the bottom—that is not what
I am recommending in this report at all—whereas better regulation
says, “How do we deliver the same standards in environmental
quality, food standards, workers’ rights and all the other things
that we regard as essential in our modern society, in a way that
is cheaper, quicker, simpler, or more digital or more modern? How
can we do that in a way that costs the providers of those things
less?” If it costs the providers less, that means they can do it
at lower cost, which means that consumers can get the same
product or service at a lower price in the first place. It is up
to everybody and it will be for all our benefit if we can do
that.
However, getting rid of red tape and regulation is one of the
hardest things to achieve in Westminster and Whitehall, because
everybody here knows that the culture of this place is framed in
terms of making new rules. That is how civil servants or—dare I
say it?—one or two MPs make their career; it is by inventing new
rules and not by getting rid of old ones. That is the culture of
this place.
Better regulation is an extremely easy thing to say and an
extremely difficult thing to do, although there have been
examples—rare ones—in the past where we have succeeded. There was
a brief flowering of success between 2010 and 2015, under when he was Prime Minister,
whereby the pro-regulatory ratchet got reversed and for a couple
of years we were genuinely making progress, and in fact local
firms and small firms and their organisations, particularly the
Federation of Small Businesses and similar bodies, noticed it and
said, “This is working”.
Unfortunately, when left office, the blob
pounced; I do not know whether a blob can pounce, but perhaps it
enveloped the new regime. When left office, the blob looked
at what worked—basically, it was having a gateway condition
saying, “If you are the Minister for paper clips, you can’t have
new rules about paper clips until you have found two old ones to
get rid of”; that was the thing that had been making things work
until then—and said, “That’s a terribly old-fashioned way of
doing it. We’ve got a much better way of doing it. Why don’t we
have a big target and we’ll hit the target and that will be
good?”
However, because the blob had got rid of all the rigour and all
the mechanisms for getting rid of the red tape, what happened
instead was that there was a huge target, which was completely
missed. In two years, we went backwards, by £8 billion-worth of
extra costs, when we had expected to remove £9 billion-worth of
extra costs. Instead of removing £9 billion-worth of extra costs,
we added £8 billion-worth, which was a £17 billion miss in two
years.
That was absolutely disastrous compared with what we had been
doing for the previous five years, and the thing that worries me
is that it is being recommended that we go back to something
rather similar. I do not care whether it is one in, one out or
one in, two out, but it is essential that we have that gateway
condition, because if we do not have it we will carry on going
backwards.
I am afraid, and very sorry to report, that the benefits of
Brexit report—another piece of bedtime reading, Mr Efford, which
I am sure you have gone through in detail—says on page 27 that we
will not reintroduce the old system at all but will stick with
the one that has just failed, and we will carry on repeating the
same mistake that we made before. I really hope that my hon.
Friend the Minister will be able to tell me that that has now
changed around, but I fear that he will be unable to. If we do
not change around, then we will fail again, and—let us be very
clear about it—that is what we are currently heading towards.
I have final thoughts on the economic regulators, Mr Efford; I am
nearly there. As I say, we have had some progress here, because,
as I mentioned, the Government have said that they are consulting
on trying to improve the statutory duties of economic regulators
to add extra competition, which should lead to shrinking the
regulators over time.
However, as I also mentioned, we do not have a date for when the
report on the economic regulators is due, so we do not know if
anything will ever be done about them; I hope that my hon. Friend
the Minister will be able to say that the Government will do
something about them. Without a date and without a firm
commitment in principle that the report will genuinely try to
normalise as much of the market as it can, outside the network of
monopolies that I was talking about, the suspicion has to be that
we are not trying to normalise these markets and that what will
happen—unacknowledged, but none the less firmly—is that there
will be no appetite for normalising as much of these markets as
we can, and that instead the preferred destination is perpetual
heavy regulation. I really hope that my hon. Friend the Minister
can reassure me that that is not the de facto intention behind
what we are currently doing.
My final point is about the final chapter in the report, which is
on subsidy control. Subsidies are a very heady political drug, if
we are not really careful. No matter the political party we
belong to, it is always tempting when lobbyists come knocking. It
does not matter whether a Member is in opposition or in
government, nor whether it is local government or national or
sub-national Government. When lobbyists come knocking, they say
how terrible it is that this big, important local employer has
been left behind—it did not invest in whatever it was it was
doing and is now 20 years out of date, so it has been overtaken
by plucky entrepreneurial upstarts from other parts of the
country or, indeed, from other countries—and they say, “Isn’t it
terrible that these jobs are now at risk? What we need is a just
a temporary wafer-thin subsidy to tide us over for a couple of
years while we fix things.” Of course, they do not fix things and
then, a couple of years later, they come back and ask for
more.
That is expensive for taxpayers and it reduces both the
productivity of industry and the long-term security and
sustainability of British jobs, which become progressively more
and more vulnerable to international competition. Ultimately, it
is the thing that did for us in the 1960s and 1970s, and which we
had enormous pain trying to fix in the 1980s and 1990s. Subsidy
control is vital. It is one of those rules that has just come
back, post Brexit, from being run by Brussels. We have a Subsidy
Control Bill before Parliament at the moment—it is in the Lords.
It will do all sorts of really good things to speed up our
subsidy control process; it is much more nimble and light-touch.
If authorities are compliant with six or seven different
principles—
The Parliamentary Under-Secretary of State for Business, Energy
and Industrial Strategy ()
Seven.
I thank the Minister for that information. If they comply with
seven different principles of good subsidy, as opposed to bad
subsidy, they can just get on with it—whether that is a local
council or a national Government Minister, or anybody in
between.
That is fine, except that we are keeping them a secret. We are
not telling anybody what the subsidies are that we are dishing
out. The EU system, which is what we are trying to replace, says
that it is necessary to disclose any subsidies above half a
million euros, which is quite a high level, actually. It means
that a lot of subsidies are never disclosed at all, particularly
if they are dished out by local councils. We are saying that it
is not necessary to declare any subsidies under half a million
pounds. The last time I looked at the euro-pound exchange rate,
that is a higher level of disclosure than the old EU system.
There are some other levels that are a bit lower for other bits
and pieces, about which I am sure the Minister will remind
us.
However, broadly speaking, we are going to declare less in
future: we will be less transparent than we were in the past.
That leaves the door open to cronyism—to local authorities or
national Governments dishing out money to their mates, secure in
the knowledge that nobody will know because we will not be able
to see. It also leaves the door open to higher levels of
subsidisation, potentially of less competitive firms, and
therefore to wasting taxpayers’ money in future. Given what is
happening to the cost of living at the moment, none of us wants
to waste a single penny of hard-won taxpayers’ money,
particularly when we have to take it as taxes in the first
place.
It is a curate’s egg. It is sort of two cheers, rather than
three, for what has been done so far. After a year, there has
been genuine progress, and I am delighted to celebrate the points
on the positive side of the ledger that I started off with.
However, there is quite a lot—marginally more—on the negative
side of the ledger; those things have not yet happened, but they
could. The advantage is that most of the reforms that I have gone
through—which have not yet happened, but which could—will not
cost the Treasury a bean. They will not cost the taxpayer a bean.
They will mean that British jobs and companies will become more
competitive, more sustainable and safer in the long term,
because, ultimately, the only thing that protects us against
international competition is the fact that we are better than the
international firms we compete against. It is a cheap route to
economic success.
I am hoping, therefore, that it is a bit of a no-brainer. It is
one of those things about which we say, “Why wouldn’t you do all
of this stuff? Why on earth would you not?” The only reason, I am
sure, is that there are genuinely significant vested interests
behind some of these things that make them difficult to shift.
However, we have a doughty warrior in the shape of the Government
Minister responding to this debate. I am therefore looking
forward to hearing how quickly he will be able to fight and smite
the various different vested interests that would otherwise slow
us down.
2.54pm
(Makerfield) (Lab)
It is a pleasure to serve under your chairmanship, Mr Efford. I
congratulate the hon. Member for Weston-super-Mare () on securing this debate and
on the review. Given his doughty defence of non-regulation, I
hesitate to propose more regulation, but I would like to see a
new competition and consumer Bill in the next session of
Parliament. It has never been more needed than now, given the
effects of the two-year pandemic and the cost of living
crisis.
The pandemic has led to more people buying online, and more
people are putting in fake reviews. That is a scam, and it has
left millions of consumers bruised, out of pocket and with little
trust in the companies trying to sell them goods and services.
More than seven in 10 consumers use online reviews to inform
purchases. They do not go down to the pub and talk to their
neighbours about their purchases; they have not been able to do
so for two years. They use online reviews.
There have been review practices across many of the largest
online platforms, including Amazon, Google and Facebook, and
multiple sectors have seen a thriving market in commissioning and
selling fake reviews. Which? has called for commissioning and
incentivising a fake review to be added to the list of
automatically unfair practices in schedule 1 to the Consumer
Protection from Unfair Trading Regulations 2008, and I support
that. Other than by looking reviews, where do people get
information? What they need is the confidence that a review
represents a verified purchase; that the review has been written
by a real individual who was not given any money or incentive to
buy a product; that the review was not for a free parcel that was
delivered to the doorstep unknowingly; and that the review is
honest. Sometimes, negative reviews are taken offline. People are
told, “We’ll give you £5 for a positive review”, and if the
review is not positive enough, they do not get the money.
There are other exploitative online practices, such as
subscription traps and drip pricing. It is not about choosing the
interests of the consumer over the interests of businesses,
because the more effective consumer protection becomes, the more
the UK economy benefits. It is a win-win. If consumers can trust
businesses and their practices, they are more inclined to buy
those companies’ products. Crucially to the businesses, people
then come back for more.
Particularly when people are thinking very carefully about how to
spend their money, it is imperative that we encourage trust in
businesses. Companies will then compete on their ability to meet
customers’ needs and provide real value, rather than on cutting
corners or passing off shoddy products. Only the best businesses
will survive, and that is as it should be. It is a partnership,
because consumers and businesses both have the same interests at
heart. Consumers want the best products at the best prices, and
businesses want to sell them those things.
An important component of the legislation is around redress and
alternative dispute resolution. Which? says that there should be
mandatory dispute resolution schemes in key sectors that have a
high volume of complaints and are often complex and high value.
We have all seen, particularly through the pandemic, the problems
that people have had getting refunds for air travel. Thousands of
covid-related flight cancellations left people out of pocket, and
the airlines have quite often chosen to ignore the law by
refusing a refund. People have waited months, if not years, for
those refunds. There are two ADR schemes in the aviation
industry, but neither is compulsory to join. Ryanair left one
scheme because it disagreed with the judgments relating to
strikes by its air crew. Jetair, Emirates and others have failed
to join any ADR scheme. If things go wrong, the passengers do not
have any redress.
In early 2019, the all-party parliamentary group on consumer
protection, which I chair, published a report calling for the
wholesale reform of the ADR platform. We looked in detail at the
various ombudsmen and ADR schemes and found enormous variation in
how they operate. Some are statutory bodies, and some are not.
Some cover all firms in the sector, because everyone has to join
them, and some do not. Some can enforce the judgments, and some
cannot. That creates total confusion for consumers, who are often
left frustrated and do not know who to go to. Air travel was one
of the areas where the statutory scheme was most keenly felt, and
that was pre covid.
Our report said that what was needed was a powerful and
accessible statutory ombudsman, which probably echoes the call
from the hon. Member for Weston-super-Mare about a 24/7 dispute
resolution platform. People do not know where to go. They have to
negotiate a difficult maze of ombudsmen. Who do they go to? There
should be a single point of entry for all complaints, which
should be passed through to the correct ombudsman. I think that
there should be an ombudsman for travel, so that people do not
think, “Some of my journey was air travel, but there was also a
bit of rail. Was it the delay on the railway that led to my
missing the plane?” It gets far too confusing for the consumer.
People often buy a package, which includes the flights and hotel.
Is that a package, or are there separate bookings for the flights
and the hotel? Some companies have said, “You booked the flights
and hotel with us, but it is not a package, because they were
booked separately.” When one part goes wrong, to whom do people
turn? That is why we need an ombudsman for the whole travel
industry; I think that is the model in Germany.
We also need to look at enforcement. The CMA is responsible for
the enforcement of consumer law in precedent setting and
market-wide cases, but it lacks the power to effectively protect
consumer rights and deter companies. In order to enforce a
decision, there is a lengthy court process, and a company can be
fined only if it fails to comply with a court order. One example
of that is the issue with the ticket seller Viagogo. It took six
years for Viagogo to be forced to change its practices and follow
the CMA guidance on the information it gives to consumers. In
Canada, however, the secondary ticketing sites Ticketmaster and
StubHub had immediate fines of 4 million Canadian dollars and 5
million Canadian dollars in costs. They also received a fine of
1.3 million Canadian dollars for not complying with a previous
warning. Compare that with a process that took six years, during
which time Viagogo could rip off consumers. It is just not good
enough.
There are other examples of companies in the travel and wedding
sectors that, despite clear guidance from the CMA, were very slow
to offer refunds and unlawfully held on to customers’ money for
months and months after the cancellation of services—by them, not
by consumers. We need a simplified process of investigation, and
we need the CMA to have greater powers—along the lines of those
enjoyed by the other UK regulators, such as the Financial Conduct
Authority and the Information Commissioner’s Office—to raise
standards and challenge companies that fail to comply. We have
the power to do that, but it needs some teeth. It is no use
having regulation and legislation unless it can be enforced
easily for consumers, who are often deterred by a long, complex
process; indeed, some businesses rely on that.
We are all consumers. Most of the time, things go smoothly, but
it is when things go wrong that the gaps in protection are
exposed. Limiting that exposure is vital in order to give
consumers the confidence to make more purchases without the undue
stress and worry that many have had to go through in the
past.
3.03pm
(Truro and Falmouth)
(Con)
It is a pleasure to serve under your chairmanship, Mr Efford. I
congratulate my hon. Friend the Member for Weston-super-Mare
() on securing this crucial
debate and on his excellent work not only on his review, but as
the UK’s anti-corruption champion. His review is a vital piece of
work and reveals how our competition policy can drive enterprise,
productivity and growth. I am pleased to recognise that more
competition and support for small businesses outside the
south-east is key to our levelling-up agenda.
I speak as the Member for Truro and Falmouth in Cornwall, which
has an economy built on fantastic small businesses, with three
quarters of local companies employing fewer than five people.
Although the terms “competition law” and “ competition policy”
might seem far removed from our everyday lives, it can be argued
that failing to create a better regulatory regime that fully
supports small businesses, consumers and fair competition has led
to higher prices and lower wages in Cornwall for much of the last
decade. We must unpick the fact that Cornwall has the lowest
productivity levels anywhere in the UK, and that places the
region at the heart of the Government’s levelling-up agenda. I
draw the House’s attention to section 6 of the report, which
shows that Britain has a well-known productivity problem,
especially outside the south-east.
Our geographical skew in productivity is not normal; only two
other European countries, Poland and Romania, have bigger
variations than we have. That difference translates into
everyone’s wages. In Cornwall, one in three workers earn below
the national living wage, and much of the employment in Cornwall
is reliant on two low-paying industry groups, namely hospitality
and retail. They are sources of pride for Cornwall and its
flourishing tourism sector, but it is inescapable that both are
sources of low pay and low productivity.
Against a backdrop of rapid change in the world of work and the
need to increase productivity, action to improve skills in
Cornwall is crucial. Investing in skills will attract more
competitive and successful firms, creating a virtuous circle that
attracts more high-skilled people to live and work in the
area—boosting productivity, jobs and wages even further.
I am in talks with BEIS and other Government officials about the
lithium that is under our feet in Cornwall. We are very lucky,
geologically. Few people realise that there is enough lithium
under the Cornish soil to power at least half of the electric
vehicles that we will need in the future. Cornwall is very good
at getting things out of the ground and sending them away, but we
need to make sure that all the processing to get the lithium to a
battery-ready status also happens in the county, creating
long-term jobs. To do that, we will have to compete with firms in
China and other overseas players. That makes it difficult, and
that is why we need to work with Government to make sure that the
processing happens locally.
I am pleased with recent progress, such as the news that the
excellent team at Truro and Penwith College have applied to the
skills accelerator programme, ushering in a new approach that
ensures that all technical education and training is based on
what employers actually need. That is yet another example of the
principal Martin Tucker and his brilliant team at Truro and
Penwith leading the way with excellence and innovation in the
learning and skills sector. It adds to their strong existing
offer, which includes free skills bootcamps in digital and
technical careers and the higher level skills project, to support
individuals looking to enhance their knowledge and develop their
careers.
We must consider all the options on the table to increase the
region’s productivity. The report makes several crucial
recommendations to reform competition policy and put consumers at
the heart of markets, and I urge the Government to consider those
recommendations. In particular, the report notes that to raise
productivity in areas such as Cornwall, we need to boost the
“local competitive temperature” by supporting small businesses to
compete with large competitors. That was what I was driving at in
my earlier intervention.
I want to highlight two areas of the report: reducing the burden
of red tape and supporting digital industries. Laws and
regulations are a crucial part of our market economy, as we have
already said. They protect staff, consumers and the environment.
I have been very vocal about the need for strong regulations on
water companies, which are currently responsible for much of the
pollution in our rivers, including the River Fal in my
constituency. I agree that we need better regulation that
maintains standards but applies them in the least costly and most
unbureaucratic way possible.
In particular, we must address the growing crisis in the fishing
sector that is caused by complicated new export rules, a lack of
clarity about fishing quotas and an increase in red tape. At this
point, I have to declare an interest as a fishwife—these are
issues that I hear about at the breakfast table daily. Those
changes have significantly hit our shellfish producers in
particular, and some businesses face the real possibility of
collapse unless we take urgent action. The fishing industry plays
a vital role in the Cornish economy, and I urge the Government to
step in and address the issues to secure its long-term
future.
We have a lot of small producers in Cornwall, and up until very
recently their only option has been to take their catch to
market. A couple of years ago, a fisherman might have received
£1.50 for a kilo of mackerel at market. They could go into the
supermarket the same day and see lesser quality, net-caught fish
of the same type—fish that had been in a net for a couple of days
and was not as fresh as line caught—and the consumer would be
paying something like £10 or £12 a kilo for it. Somebody is
making an awful lot of money out of that fish, and it is not the
food producer; it is not the fisherman. I am pleased that the
Government have been encouraging direct sales, but I encourage
them to further reduce the red tape that these boys and girls
have to put themselves through to ensure that they can sell
directly to farm shops and even, if possible, directly to
supermarkets.
I support the report’s proposals for a new pro-competition regime
for digital markets. Digital technologies bring us many benefits,
transforming our economy, society and daily lives. However, there
are downsides caused by firms with enormous network and digital
data monopolies, so we must ensure that digital regulation
promotes competition and innovation. Digital industries are a
growing part of the economy in Cornwall, which has a rapidly
expanding digital and creative community that has grown by 76%
since 2010. I will do all I can to support the Government to
ensure that we build a pro-growth data regime that will allow the
digital industry in Cornwall to thrive.
Improving productivity in areas such as Cornwall is key to
levelling up in the UK, and that is why it is important that we
invest in skills and reform to make better regulation in
industries such as fishing and all the way to digital markets. I
look forward to supporting the Government as they consider the
recommendations of the report, and I will continue to champion
all our small businesses, innovation and competition now and in
the years to come.
3.10pm
(Folkestone and Hythe)
(Con)
It is a pleasure to serve under your chairmanship, Mr Efford. I
congratulate my hon. Friend the Member for Weston-super-Mare
() on his report and on securing
this important debate. I particularly want to address his
comments on the digital markets unit, which he says has been set
up in shadow form. We eagerly anticipate the Queen’s Speech to
see whether there is legislation in the next Session to give the
unit the power that it needs.
So much of our commerce and consumer interaction takes place
through digital services. We have seen that more than ever during
the pandemic. They are an integral part of the economy. It is
right that we question and challenge whether digital markets are
truly competitive, and whether the very large players that
dominate them are guilty of abuse of market power, given the
great positions that they hold.
It is tempting to think, “There are a lot of big digital
companies; presumably they all compete against each other, and
that creates a fair market.” When we break that market down, we
see a series of monopolies in each sector. Unsurprisingly, Google
has 92% of the world’s search business; Chrome, which is owned by
Google, has 62% of the browser market; and Facebook and Google
together control about 70% of the digital display advertising
market worldwide.
Mobile phones run on one of two operating systems: 70% run on the
Android operating system, which is owned by Google, and 30% on
iOS, which is owned by Apple. You might think, “Well, at least
there is a market split there,” but they are both monopolies.
Apple customers —I am one; I have an iPhone—have no choice but to
purchase apps through the App Store; there is no interoperable or
alternative system. I cannot use a different app store system,
such as the Google app store, to download apps on to an Apple
product, or the other way around. The mobile communication
devices market, which is central to the world economy, is
dominated by only two operating systems, both of which are
monopolies for their users.
As for the messaging app market in the UK, WhatsApp has 75%
market penetration. The next most popular messaging app is
Facebook Messenger, which has nearly 60% market penetration—that
is, 60% of people in this market use it. Of course, people have
multiple messaging apps. Both are owned by the same company.
Across digital markets, there are these relative monopolies.
Is there evidence of abuse of market power? There is certainly
evidence of these companies treating customers differently. There
is evidence that Apple has different policies on charges for
selling through the App Store for different companies. It does
not charge everyone the same amount. Facebook has allowed
different businesses to acquire different levels of Facebook data
to help them drive their business through the Facebook systems,
depending on the value of the commercial relationship to
Facebook. When I chaired the Digital, Culture, Media and Sport
Select Committee, we published evidence that we secured from an
American app developer that showed that Facebook sometimes made
arbitrary determinations about whether an app developer should
have access to the Facebook graph at all; it depended on whether
Facebook thought that the product that the company was developing
was a threat to its business.
Some people may remember from the dim and distant past the short
film app called Vine, which was very popular. People uploaded
very short films to it. Mark Zuckerberg personally decided that
Vine was acquiring too much Facebook data, so Facebook kicked
Vine off the platform. An email was published in which Mark
Zuckerberg was asked to confirm that he wanted to do that, and he
replied, “Yup, go for it.” In our report, the creators of Vine
said they remembered that moment as though it were yesterday,
because it was the moment that effectively killed their business.
The chief exec of a global tech company can, like the Emperor
Augustus, put their thumb up or down, and determine whether a
business is allowed to succeed, based on his assessment of
whether that business is a competitor to his.
We often say, “Why is it that, particularly in the tech sector,
although the UK produces brilliant, thriving companies, they do
not go to scale?” One of the reasons is that if they are too
successful, they are squeezed out of the market by bigger,
dominant players, which either deny them fair access to customers
through their platform, give them the option of being acquired,
or drive them out of business altogether.
There have been competition investigations into preferential
ranking on Apple and Google systems, to see whether Google search
results favour businesses with which Google has a commercial
relationship, with to the detriment of others that it sees as
competitors. Amazon can monitor whether a product is successful,
who is buying it, and, if it is too successful, whether it should
copy it and launch its own product. Amazon does not give customer
purchase data to businesses that sell through Amazon. Amazon is
both the creator of the infrastructure through which businesses
sell to their customers, and sells its own products alongside
them, giving it immense market power.
We need a digital markets unit that ensures not only that
consumers are treated fairly, that they have fair pricing and
that there is fair competition among products, but that
businesses that reach their customers through other tech
platforms are treated fairly. It should ensure that businesses
pay a fair rate for advertising, have fair access to data
relative to other businesses, and are not a victim of aggressive
pricing against them by the platform, or dis-ranked or downgraded
through pure prejudice. All those aspects are central to the
working of the digital economy today, and that is why it is
important that we have a digital markets unit with the ability to
launch investigations for evidence of tech platforms abusing
their market power over other businesses, to the detriment of
consumer interest.
3.16pm
(North Ayrshire and Arran)
(SNP)
I am delighted to participate in this debate on UK competition
and consumer policy in response to the Penrose review. I pay
tribute to the hon. Member for Weston-super-Mare () for all his work on the
review. The goals of the Penrose review, which are to improve
consumer choice and outcomes, are, of course, very important;
they are things that we can all sign up to. Now more than ever,
with household budgets being badly squeezed in this cost of
living crisis, consumers must be supported, so that they can
secure the best value for money and have sufficient protection
under the law. For that to happen, we need UK competition and
consumer protection that is fit for the modern age.
Consumers need confidence that if they fall victim to
exploitation and unscrupulous practices, there is redress and the
consumer protection that they need and deserve. It is clear that
some markets simply do not work for the consumer. I understand
that the clear statement of intent in the Penrose review was that
markets must work for people, not the other way round. Who could
argue with that?
Consumer confidence is essential for economic growth, so it is
worrying that research by consumer champion Which? has found that
up to one third of consumers experience at least one problem with
a product or service every year. That not only causes financial
loss and anxiety but has a detrimental impact on consumer
confidence. We all know that there are gaps in consumer
protection and enforcement, some of which have been exacerbated
by the pandemic. For example, we all witnessed how the disruption
to the travel industry during covid left passengers out of pocket
when airlines either refused to pay for cancelled flights or
delayed refunds.
Digital markets are not subject to the same regulations as their
offline counterparts, and that opens the door to fake products
reviews, which have exploded on online marketplaces. We heard a
lot about that from the hon. Member for Makerfield (). Members in all parts of
this Chamber have expressed concerns about digital markets, and
our constituents share those concerns.
The situation is made worse by the fact that regulators do not
have the necessary powers to hold companies to account when the
law is flouted. The Competition and Markets Authority does what
it can to uphold consumer law, but its investigations can take
years and tend to result in commitments instead of fines, and
offer little in the way of deterrents for those who would flout
the law. The problem is that to be more effective, the CMA needs
more powers to properly perform the task of protecting consumer
rights.
I note with interest the conclusions of the Penrose review, which
proposes that the Competition and Markets Authority be given
sharper teeth, so that it has increased power to drive consumer
rights, supply-side reforms and productivity improvements. It
also proposes a streamlined legislative framework for UK
competition and consumer policy.
Of greater interest is the question of which of the Penrose
conclusions the UK Government will take forward. Indeed, if the
Penrose review is implemented in full, it could constitute the
biggest shake-up of the UK’s competition and consumer law regime
since the creation of the Competition and Markets Authority in
2014. The changes would range from providing the Competition and
Markets Authority with the same powers to prosecute consumer law
cases as it has for competition law investigations to reforming
sectoral regulations. The review contains some very interesting
ideas and would give the Competition and Markets Authority
significantly increased powers.
However, concerns have been expressed that concentrating such
increased power in the Competition and Markets Authority at a
time when it is adapting to its new post-Brexit case load and the
challenges of a digitised economy could be very challenging
indeed for the CMA. We simply do not know yet what the Government
response to the Penrose review will be, although it does appear—I
underline the word “appear”—that the Chancellor and the Business
Secretary have welcomed the recommendations. The question is:
where do we go from here?
We have all waited so long. The chair of the Competition and
Markets Authority, , set out recommendations for
reform in 2019. In 2020, the hon. Member for Weston-super-Mare
was asked by the Government to look into competition, and he
published his report last year. The UK Government recognised the
need to reform the enforcement regime in their 2019 manifesto,
and the Departments for Business, Energy and Industrial Strategy,
and for Digital, Culture, Media and Sport, have undertaken
consultations.
Last year, the Business Secretary set out plans to bolster
competition regimes, but that must be underpinned by legislation.
Consumer and competition policy has been under review for over
four years, which has meant that the challenges that consumers
face in the marketplace have continued, and have often become
much more difficult. If the Competition and Markets Authority had
more power, as other regulators do—enough power to protect
consumers and hold companies accountable for breaking consumer
law—we could raise standards in the consumer marketplace.
We can see clearly what the lack of such powers can lead to in
practice. We have had the example of the secondary ticketing
platform Viagogo for six years; after the threat of legal action,
it finally changed its practices and paid attention to the
Competition and Markets Authority guidance on advising consumers.
Had the immediate imposition of fines for not complying with
guidance been an option, it would not have taken six years for
Viagogo to comply, and for us to secure the changes that
everybody wanted. We have all seen that the Competition and
Markets Authority lacked the power it needed, during the time of
covid disruption, to ensure that consumers were refunded in a
reasonable timeframe by some players in the travel and wedding
sectors.
A consumer and competition Bill could tackle the bad business
practices that harm consumers and consumer confidence. There
could be simpler investigation procedures, and fines could be
imposed, so that matters were not dragged through the courts in
lengthy processes, as the hon. Member for Weston-super-Mare said.
That would be nothing but a boon to consumer confidence and
protection.
I agree with the call in the report for stronger protections for
consumers against the so-called loyalty penalty, unfair
contractual terms, perceived attempts by digital businesses to
nudge consumers into making decisions, making it hard for
consumers to exit contracts, and of course the practice of
creating an unreal sense of urgency to pressurise consumers into
making purchases, as well as trapping them in subscriptions.
A code of conduct would benefit both business and consumers. It
would ensure that the largest online platforms did not abuse
their market power. There would also be an alternative dispute
resolution scheme that offered an efficient, affordable and
proportionate route for resolving difficulties relating to
high-value transactions while avoiding the complexity and cost of
going to small claims court.
Finally, a consumer and competition Bill must be introduced in
the upcoming programme for Government. That would be the point at
which all the work that has been done at last comes to
fruition—when a competition and enforcement framework fit for the
modern economy is delivered through legislation. There is real
impatience for the Government to finally commit to action on
these important consumer protection matters. It is not clear how
far the Government will go in improving competition and consumer
policy. We do not know how they will interpret and implement the
recommendations of the Penrose review. Perhaps the Minister will
enlighten us.
Alongside the proposals made by the chair of the Competition and
Markets Authority, , we have had consultations by
the Department for Business, Energy and Industrial Strategy and
the Department for Digital, Culture, Media and Sport, and the
Penrose review. What we have not yet had is the introduction of a
consumer and competition Bill. We all look forward to a Bill with
proper teeth that will confer real power on the Competition and
Markets Authority, so that it can support consumer confidence and
create a marketplace in which the consumer is protected, and in
which, as the Penrose review boldly set out, the market works for
people, not the other way around.
I look forward to this long-promised, long-awaited and
much-anticipated Bill. I hope the Minister will at least say when
we will be able to see and scrutinise it.
3.26pm
(Feltham and Heston)
(Lab/Co-op)
It is a pleasure to serve under your chairship, Mr Efford. I
thank the hon. Member for Weston-super-Mare () for initiating this debate,
and for his work on this issue. His very important “Power to the
People” report was published around a year ago. In his opening
remarks, he clearly laid out the sentiments and recommendations
of the report, as well as, importantly, the context of declining
competitiveness, the productivity challenge we face and the
importance of making sure that we can act against the
non-compliance of companies that do not play their part, so that
we can ensure a fair regime for all businesses and for consumers.
He rightly raised points about the vested interests that distort
our markets.
Competition law seeks to curb practices that undermine or
restrict competition to the detriment of consumers. Those
practices can include a firm’s abuse of its dominant market
position, anti-competitive practices, and mergers or takeovers
that, if allowed, would result in a substantial lessening of
competition. There has been a rapid increase in takeovers and
mergers, particularly during the pandemic lockdowns, so that is
an area that needs further work. I will come back to that.
Labour welcomed the Penrose report, and also highlighted where it
needed to go further. UK markets are becoming more concentrated,
and that hits consumers and workers, and stops small businesses
in their tracks and prevents them from progressing. are stopping
small businesses in their tracks. We want a re-evaluation of the
role of the Competition and Markets Authority to ensure that it
has the tools to tackle the growing concentration of market
power.
We may disagree on rolling back economic regulation, but the
issue is not necessarily the principle; it is more about asking
whether we have the regulations we need for effective regulation
of markets for consumers. That may not be about quantity; I think
it is about quality. That is where the debate needs to start. I
am not interested in regulation for regulation’s sake. For me,
regulation is about purpose; it is about making sure that it will
be effective and deliver the outcomes that we believe are
necessary. We need more robust competition policy; we need to
crack down on tax avoidance, and challenge mergers and
acquisitions that mean taking on unsustainable debt, or that are
not in Britain’s long-term strategic interests.
I thank all hon. Members who have contributed; they have made
important and distinct contributions highlighted different areas
of the subject. We in this House have long known about the work
that my hon. Friend the Member for Makerfield () does on consumer
protection. She raised important issues around fake
reviews—reviews are part of how consumers are informed—and around
how action can be taken when consumers are misinformed. She also
raised the important point that consumers and businesses have a
common interest in making sure that markets work effectively and
fairly. She highlighted the importance of ensuring that reform is
based on how consumers behave today, how the market works and how
consumers receive their goods and services. Many of those issues
are interconnected. She rightly alluded to the important work of
Which? in this area, and I thank it for its contribution.
The hon. Member for Truro and Falmouth () shared a rich picture
of her constituency, the opportunities and sectoral issues in her
local economy and the challenges in taking forward some of those
opportunities. The hon. Member for Folkestone and Hythe () highlighted clearly the
dominance of power of the social media companies, which is an
important backdrop to the digital markets reform that we have
discussed. The hon. Member for North Ayrshire and Arran () talked about the
importance of value for money and consumer protection. Some of
the issues that she raised, like those raised by my hon. Friend
the Member for Makerfield, were very powerful.
Focusing on consumer interest has never been more important given
the cost of living crisis that consumers face. Inflation is out
of control, with energy, food and petrol prices rocketing. It is
not just about global factors; we know that poor Government
economic management has left us uniquely exposed. We have a buy
now, pay later loan scheme for energy bills, rather than dealing
with the problems in our energy market. We are very worried about
raising taxes on working people and businesses at the worst
possible time. In parallel to our debate, an Opposition day
debate is taking place to call on the Government, again, to stop
the national insurance rise in April.
There has been a long journey of reform. Hon. Members will be
aware than when Labour was in power, we argued strongly that UK
regulation of anti-competitive practices was weak. That led to
one of our first pieces of legislation, the Competition Act 1998.
That recent journey is worth noting, because, as my hon. Friend
the Member for Makerfield said, it has been four years since the
Secretary of State for Business, Energy and Industrial Strategy
asked the CMA for proposals to better protect consumers in the
digital economy and improve public trust in markets.
The then CMA chairman, , outlined his proposals to the
Secretary of State in a letter in 2019. The Penrose review
followed in February 2021. Last summer, the Government published
two consultation documents—the first on reforming competition and
consumer policy and the second on a pro-competition regime for
digital markets. Both sets of proposals would require legislation
to take forward some of the challenges raised, but the Government
have yet to publish their response to either of those
consultations.
I recognise that both the Penrose review and the Government’s
consultation represent some progress in addressing the rules
governing the UK’s companies and markets, not least as they
recognise that reform is necessary. They are also vehicles for
reforming the UK anti-trust regime post covid and post Brexit.
The Penrose review is very important in that respect. The
existing system, however, is no longer serving consumers
appropriately, and is not fit for purpose in a digital age. It
could lead to new monopolies created at any time in new
markets.
It sounds as though the hon. Lady is joining other Members in
saying that we need a new competition and consumer Act to fix
some of those things. Could she confirm that that is the Labour
party’s position? I think that is what she is saying, but I do
not want to put words in her mouth.
I will come on to that, but I think we need legislation. We hope
that will be announced in the next Queen’s Speech, but I will
come back to that.
There seems to be broad consensus for providing the regulators,
including the CMA and the Competition Appeal Tribunal, with more
powers to protect consumers and hold companies accountable if
they are not found to be playing by the rules. That is a positive
step. However, so far—I say this gently—the Penrose review and
the Government’s consultation are a missed opportunity for a more
fundamental review and reform of the UK marketplace. Even the
CMA, which is now responsible for all anti-competitive practices
that affect UK markets and consumers, has said that comments in
the Government’s consultation on reforming competition and
consumer policy amounted to
“incremental, rather than radical, change to the competition
regime.”
Let me mention resources, which are needed to make any regime
effective, an issue that was raised yesterday in the debate on
economic crime. Powers and resources for investigation and
enforcement are absolutely critical. They are the other side of
the coin to policy, and are about how we make sure that any
regime is implemented effectively.
I want to focus on four areas to which I hope the Minister will
respond. In large part, they reflect the comments already made,
with one or two extra points.
First, on digital competition and regulation, digital is changing
our economy. It is changing how the economy works, the products
we have, how we receive services, how consumers purchase those
services and how businesses trade with each other. There is a
huge concentration of power in the big digital firms, with
consequences for monopolisation, consumer rights and prices, as
well as access to markets for new firms, as has been mentioned
already. We know that tackling these issues needs international
co-operation.
The Government have embarked on the creation of a digital markets
unit in the CMA, which was set up on a non-statutory basis last
April. I hope we will hear when that will be moved to a statutory
footing and be given the teeth it needs.
Will Bills on competition and consumer law reform and on digital
markets be in the Queen’s Speech? Perhaps the Minister can share
with us in this Chamber—we will take it no further; it will stay
within these four walls—whether that legislation will come
forward.
Secondly, on powers for the CMA and the speeding up of
investigations, the Penrose review made a recommendation for a
taskforce on how we can make sure that CMA investigations are
more effective. It is important to get justice for consumers, as
the hon. Member for Weston-super-Mare said. What more are the
Government planning to do in that area? There are other instances
of unfairness and questionable policy. One example really struck
me before Christmas. Royal Mail highlighted 23 areas that would
see a reduction in service pre-Christmas, but that came on the
back of £400 million in dividends being announced the month
before. It does not seem right that there is no accountability
for that sort of decision making.
There is some positive news. In its response to the Penrose
review, the CMA announced that it is creating a dedicated
microeconomic unit, which the hon. Member for Weston-super-Mare
called for, and which I understand will be based in Darlington at
the Treasury campus.
Thirdly, on the public interest test, Labour has proposed the
introduction of a broad public interest test for mergers and
acquisitions. That would give the Government powers to review
transactions, impose conditions and block transactions where they
could have negative, long-term implications for the UK’s
industrial strategy, economy and jobs. The Government have powers
under the Enterprise Act 2002 to intervene in mergers and
acquisitions where they raise issues of national security,
stability of the UK financial system, media plurality or
maintaining in the UK the ability to combat and mitigate the
effects of public health emergencies.
We are calling for the Enterprise Act 2016 to be expanded to
include a public interest test where an acquisition may have
long-term implications for the UK’s industrial strategy. In our
view, that goes further than the Penrose review in strengthening
the interests of consumers, and we believe that we need a debate
on how the CMA should move past narrow competition and consumer
interests to public interest. On takeovers and mergers, that
could apply to consumer interest but also to the impact on supply
chains, employees and the public interest more generally, which
has implications for consumer interests. As is consistent with
the approach that the Minister will know we took on the Subsidy
Control Bill, we need the CMA to have more diverse voices in its
leadership, including reforms to the authority to make it more
representative of the nations and regions of the UK.
I will just comment briefly on hollowed-out local enforcement.
Our consumer protection regime has been weakened by 10 years of
degradation of local authority trading standards teams. That is a
serious issue. The number of LATS officers has been cut by more
than 50% since 2010, while 45% of local authority trading
standards teams say they do not have the resources to deal with
consumer issues in their area. I note that the Penrose review has
called for action on that and I would be grateful for the
Minister’s confirmation that some of the recommendations in the
review will form part of his package of reforms later this
year.
In conclusion, Labour welcomes competition and consumer choice in
the UK as a sign of a healthy, functioning market economy. We are
committed to making the UK the best place in the world to start
and grow a business, and we believe that that is important as
part of a pro-business, pro-society, pro-worker agenda to be
built for Britain. We are ready and waiting for Parliament to
have the opportunity to act and to build on the Penrose review.
We believe that the Government have been a little too slow, so I
hope that the Minister will give us confidence that things will
be speeded up. I look forward to working with him and with
colleagues from across the House on this important agenda as it
moves forward.
3.41pm
The Parliamentary Under-Secretary of State for Business, Energy
and Industrial Strategy ()
It is a pleasure to serve under your chairmanship, Mr Efford.
I congratulate my hon. Friend the Member for Weston-super-Mare
() on securing the debate and on
his report. Wolfie Smith will be turning in his Afghan coat when
he sees that “Power to the People” has become the mantra for
fixing broken markets to encourage good competition and free
markets, but the report is an interesting read. That reference
got tumbleweed from some of the younger Members, but I hope that
my hon. Friend remembers Wolfie Smith.
My hon. Friend’s report is an important contribution to the
debate on reforming the UK’s competition policy. It has had a
significant role in shaping the Government’s thinking on the
priorities for reform, and I reiterate my thanks to him for his
work and for his continuing engagement with and advocacy for
reform.
In the report, my hon. Friend argues that the UK’s competition
and consumer regime should be one of the best in the world and
the Government are absolutely four-square behind that objective.
Now that the UK has left the EU, we must build on this country’s
innovative foundations to create a robust and agile economy that
works for everyone and that is fit for future generations.
Competition and consumer policy has a central role in creating a
thriving free market economy that encourages innovation,
enterprise, growth and productivity. Competition policy is
crucial in creating the right conditions for healthy competition
between traders in markets to win over consumers by offering the
best deals and innovation. Consumer policy is vital in
underpinning consumer confidence. It empowers consumers to engage
in markets in an assured manner, knowing that they have a strong
set of legal rights that will be respected and enforced.
That is why we committed in our manifesto to give the CMA
enhanced powers to tackle consumer rip-offs and bad business
practices. It is also why the Government committed in our plan
for growth to the UK’s having a best in class competition regime
that will raise innovation and investment across the economy.
An effective competition and consumer policy will help us to
build back a better and fairer economy, giving businesses
confidence that they are competing on fair terms and giving the
public confidence that they are getting a good deal. The UK’s
competition regime is already well regarded internationally, so
we are starting from a strong foundation. However, we should
always strive to be better and to go further.
Markets and the way that consumers and businesses engage with
each other have changed dramatically since the current
legislation was enacted. That change is particularly stark in the
digital economy. The tech revolution has brought huge benefits.
Recent research has shown that about 15% of all businesses have
adopted at least one artificial intelligence technology. In
recent years, we have also seen that some digital markets have
certain characteristics that make them more prone to weak
competition.
Despite the actions that the UK has taken to promote competition,
there is evidence from the CMA that competition may have weakened
over the last 20 years. In 2020, the Government commissioned the
CMA to produce an expert state of competition assessment to
improve our collective understanding of the level and nature of
competition across the UK economy. In its first “State of UK
Competition” report, the CMA found that mark-ups, the ratio of
prices to costs, had increased by 7% from 2000 to 2018. It found
that in 2018 the average combined market share of the 10 largest
firms in an industry was 3% higher than in 1998. It is essential
that the competition regime does more to encourage and maintain
competitive markets.
The Government published two consultations on legislative reforms
in July last year, building on the work of my hon. Friend the
Member for Weston-super-Mare. The consultation, “Reforming
Competition and Consumer Policy”, set out a vision for the future
of our competition and consumer policy. The separate
consultation, “A New Pro-Competition Regime for Digital Markets”,
set out a vision for a new agile and flexible regime to promote
competition in digital markets, something that my hon. Friends
the Members for Weston-super-Mare and for Folkestone and Hythe
() highlighted that we need to
improve.
The package of reforms in the Government’s two consultations
shares the ambitions of the report by my hon. Friend the Member
for Weston-super-Mare. Those proposals seek to enhance the powers
of the CMA and consumers’ rights, and ensure that those rights
are robustly enforced. They will work to protect consumers and
help businesses thrive. In addition to sharing those ambitions,
my hon. Friend’s detailed report has had a considerable influence
on where Government see opportunities for reform.
Will the Minister clarify when the Government expect to respond
to the consultations he mentions? Clearly, they will inform what
might or might not be in any future competition and consumer
Act.
Indeed. My hon. Friend is right to have used the near anniversary
of his report as an opportunity to discuss the issue.
Unfortunately, he has slightly missed the target of the
consultation response, which we hope to bring forward very
shortly. To answer my hon. Friend the Member for Truro and
Falmouth (), the Penrose report did
not need Her Majesty to give a notification that it was coming
forward. Unfortunately, I cannot pre-empt what Her Majesty will
say in the Queen’s Speech about future legislation.
A central recommendation of the Penrose report, which my hon.
Friend the Member for Weston-super-Mare has repeated today, is
that the Government should take steps to ensure that the
enforcement of competition and consumer law speeds up to keep
pace with the modern digitising economy. We agree and propose a
range of measures to make enforcement more efficient. For
instance, we propose that the CMA should have stronger powers to
penalise businesses that obstruct or slow down investigation. The
Government have also proposed new ways for businesses and the CMA
to reach agreements on the actions needed to resolve competition
issues in market-wide investigations and merger reviews. Both
those changes were recommended by my hon. Friend in his
report.
He also recognised the need for UK competition regulators to work
in partnership with regulators overseas, to help address
competition and consumer issues that span borders. We agree that
effective international co-operation is an important part of the
UK’s competition and consumer regime. Promoting that co-operation
is a key objective in our free trade agreements, and we have
successfully secured text on that in the UK’s recent agreements
with Australia and New Zealand. We have consulted on legislative
proposals to ensure that the CMA and consumer authorities can
work as effectively as possible with their international
counterparts.
My hon. Friend’s report also emphasised the role of consumer
protection law in empowering consumers and driving effective
competition. We agree that our already strong consumer rights
framework must continue to support consumers into the future,
allowing them to benefit from new technology and business models
and to feel empowered to make the best decisions available to
them. We have consulted on measures to tackle subscription traps,
where a consumer enters into a subscription for a product or
service but has difficulty leaving. We have also consulted on
measures to tackle fake reviews, as mentioned by the hon. Member
for Makerfield (), which undermine
competition and give unfair advantage to traders who are willing
to use them.
In taking steps to strengthen the protections for consumers, the
Government are aware of the need to consider any new burdens on
businesses. We want to ensure that consumers get that fair deal
and that businesses are not overburdened by regulatory barriers.
My hon. Friend the Member for Weston-super-Mare is absolutely
right to talk about better regulation, and I will speak a little
more about that, if I have time.
My hon. Friend talked about how we can have better dispute
resolution, because when consumers enforce their rights, poorly
performing firms face more pressure, and consumers know they can
trust the system to be on their side if they need it. That is
what we need.
The Minister is being very generous. I just want to press him a
bit on the point about better regulation. So far, he has not said
that he wants to go back to one in, one out, or to one in, two
out. Could he clarify what mechanism the Government have to
ensure that better regulation happens, as opposed to being wished
for with a target that will not be hit?
We consulted on reforming the better regulation framework, and
the Government do not think that a one in, two out rule—or
whatever number out—is consistent with delivering world-class
regulation to support the economy in adapting to a new wave of
the technological revolution or in achieving net zero, so we want
to reduce costs to business wherever we sensibly can do so and
regulate only where strictly necessary. We intend to do that by
looking at the merits of each case rather than using the one in,
two out system, and we plan to change the better regulation
system so that it will do that. However, it is very important
that we get the balance right.
The Government believe that a well-functioning alternative
dispute resolution system can make markets work more effectively,
increase consumer confidence in spending and generate higher
trader compliance with the law. It is an important avenue to
redress for consumers that more easily allows for mediated
settlements and is less confrontational than a court process,
which is often more costly and time intensive, so we sought views
on proposals to enhance the role of ADR in resolving consumer
disputes.
My hon. Friend the Member for Weston-super-Mare also recommended
that the CMA’s civil consumer enforcement powers should be
upgraded, which would allow it to decide cases and impose fines
in the same way as it does for civil enforcement of competition
law. Again, we sought views on empowering the CMA to enforce
consumer law directly, and we consulted on giving the CMA new
powers to decide whether consumer law has been broken. Under the
proposal, the CMA could directly impose directions, remedies or
monetary penalties on firms that mistreat their customers without
having to go through the courts, as is currently the case. That
would allow the CMA to intervene earlier and to go further.
My hon. Friend the Member for Weston-super-Mare also mentioned
the CAT. I have to say that although there are plenty more things
that the CAT could do, changes have been brought on by covid. I
visited CAT’s virtual court the other day, when it heard the case
of Newcastle United’s takeover by the Saudi buyers. It had 35,000
people tuning in, which is more than all but the top nine average
gates in the premier league, so a lot of Geordies and Newcastle
fans elsewhere are now experts on competition law—I am not sure
whether that is a good thing or a bad thing. None the less, it
really shines a light—being with the transparency tsar—on the
work of the CAT and the competition regime.
Clearly, there are also challenges in some markets in the digital
economy, which my hon. Friend the Member for Folkestone and Hythe
talked about. That is why we looked at what we can do to have a
bespoke regime in the digital consultation. Frankly, government
is not particularly good at keeping up with technology—I am
talking about government as an overall body, rather than any
particular government—so it is right that the market looks at how
we can introduce conduct requirements and how we can have
pro-competitive interventions by the digital market unit to keep
up with an ever-changing regime. We also consulted on a merger
regime, which is exactly the point that my hon. Friend the Member
for Folkestone and Hythe was talking about—the so-called killer
acquisitions and other stifling of innovation. I remember the
days of Netscape, Mozilla Firefox and all the other browsers that
were available but have now fallen by the wayside—again,
tumbleweed from my hon. Friend the Member for Bolsover (), who is far younger than
me.
My hon. Friend the Member for Truro and Falmouth talked about
Cornwall. She did not just talk about regulation and competition
regimes and legislation to promote things such as the direct
sales of fish and the secondary industries around the exciting
opportunities for lithium. Actually, it is about promoting
enterprise and innovation. If regulation is there, that is
fantastic, but it does not always need to resort back to a
constructed regime if there are businesses ready to grab
opportunities. That needs to be part of a suite of measures to
ensure that the UK is the best place to start, grow and scale up
a business. Part of that is the strategy that BEIS is coming up
with, to show that we are ready to invest in—and are investing
in—and support, for the long term, those kinds of technologies,
which will give businesses the confidence to invest in areas such
as Truro and Falmouth in order to make the most of that.
Looking at some other areas, the hon. Member for Makerfield
talked about weddings. That was an interesting point about the
covid pandemic, because I think that shows the difficulty of
having a consumer policy. I was the Minister charged with
engaging with the wedding sector, and that was a challenge. We
had brides and grooms looking forward to their special day, which
costs a lot of money. The whole point about the wedding sector is
that it builds up anticipation and expectation. Clearly, however,
venues and organisers especially had spent a lot of money and had
a lot of reservations, but they have only a single day to provide
their service. When they were compelled to lock down, or when
demand was stifled, if they had refunded everything in one go,
they would have been out of business. The balance was hugely
difficult, with a lot of arguments between them and the CMA
within that. I am glad that we got through that, largely, and
that we were able to navigate through it by working with the CMA
and the sector to make progress.
I will conclude on the report of my hon. Friend the Member for
Weston-super-Mare, because I want to give him time to respond.
His report represents a significant milestone in the process of
reforming competition and consumer policy. I reiterate my thanks
for his work. We will continue the conversation as we bring
legislation to bear, as we make the changes where primary
legislation is required, despite the fact that changes are
already happening. He has acknowledged the direct impact of some
of his proposals, on which we have consulted, so we will bring
that all together. I continue to work with stakeholders—I spoke
with them only last week on this very subject—and we are
carefully considering the feedback. We will come back with
measures in good time.
3.57pm
I thank all hon. Members for their contributions to the debate.
One thing that has been very clear is that everyone present wants
us to go further and faster. Everyone is saying, “Get on with it.
Why are we not moving more quickly?” I think it is the only time
in my life that I have ever been outflanked on a competition
issue by the Labour Front Bencher—I am paraphrasing the hon.
Member for Feltham and Heston ()—who agreed with a great
deal in the report but would like to go further in a few areas.
Even without that, the clear message from everyone who spoke is
that we agree with most of this and we want it to happen quickly,
please, and to go further. Radicalism, not incrementalism, has
been the universal message.
My hon. Friend the Minister can take away a reassuring message
that, perhaps contrary to what he might have expected, there is
cross-party agreement on more competition and more consumer
rights, because from that comes a better and more trusting
economy, and therefore a more productive and high-wage economy.
At the start of the debate, I was not sure that I would get that,
but it has been clear that that is where we are. However, we will
need to push him a bit, because he did not mention a couple of
things in his remarks, such as the stuff about whether we can
further reform some of the economically regulated sectors, to
normalise as much of them as we can to ensure that we do not need
extra protections, because the existing ones will be enough. It
looks as if he might not have got to a section of his speech, so
it would be lovely if he commits to that when we get to the
primary legislation.
The Minister was also clear that there will be primary
legislation. I appreciate that he cannot give too many details in
advance of the Queen’s Speech. However, it is clear that we
cannot have the digital markets unit functioning effectively
without primary legislation. Therefore, more progress will be
needed. He was very clear about the shortcomings—as he sees
them—of the one in, one out mechanism, or the one in, two out
mechanism, for better regulation and about the fact that he has a
mechanism, he thinks, for an alternative approach that will work,
but when I asked him about how, we just got a repetition of what,
rather than how, and there was no detail behind it. I am sure
that he has that, and I hope that he will come around to
describing it in detail in public shortly, because at the moment
it is a bit of a mystery. Without it, we will have nothing that
works.
That said, I again thank everyone for participating and the
Minister for his comments. I think we are making progress. We
have an awfully long way still to travel.
Question put and agreed to.
Resolved,
That this House has considered UK competition and consumer policy
in response to the Penrose review.
|