New IEA/Civitas report outlines deregulatory and tax-cutting measures to reboot Britain
NEW REPORT OUTLINES DEREGULATORY AND TAX-CUTTING MEASURES TO REBOOT
BRITAIN The crisis does not signal a failure of capitalism
nor the need for permanent increase in government intervention or
public spending, says new briefing paper from the IEA and
Civitas The risks of this crisis to the UK economy should not
be downplayed; The decline will be huge – and
lifting the lockdown may not be sufficient in itself to allow
a...Request free trial
NEW REPORT OUTLINES DEREGULATORY AND TAX-CUTTING MEASURES
TO REBOOT BRITAIN
The uncertainty created by the Covid-19 crisis has
reinvigorated many old debates about the role of the state, says
a new
report from the Institute of
Economic Affairs and Civitas, written by IEA Economics Fellow
Julian Jessop and IEA Editorial and
Research Fellow Professor Len Shackleton. This crisis has highlighted the flexibility of private businesses and civil society – and illustrated weaknesses in state planning. In particular, the UK’s healthcare system has struggled to keep up with those in other countries, notably Germany, where market forces play a bigger part. Nor is this a ‘failure of capitalism’. Activity has slumped partly because the state itself has temporarily shut down large parts of the economy. But the relative flexibility of the UK economy and labour markets could help activity and employment to bounce back, provided businesses and employers are not saddled with additional costs. However, the risks to the economy should not be downplayed. The initial decline in activity may prove to be smaller than some fear, but it will still be huge, and lifting the lockdown may not be sufficient in itself to allow a robust and speedy recovery. There is also plenty of evidence that the official lockdown has exacerbated the economic impact. Indeed, if the official lockdown were not having any additional effects on behaviour and hence on economic activity, it would prompt the question of why it is needed at all. Historical precedents suggest that the pandemic could last until the summer of 2021. In the meantime, many businesses (restaurants, clubs, theatres) simply cannot operate in the new world of social distancing and will fail. Others (such as air travel) are going to suffer severe reductions in output and will need a new business model. There could be substantial frictional unemployment as people take time to transition from one sector to another. But if markets are liberalised and allowed to operate freely as we emerge from lockdown, the recovery may still be quicker than many think, as was the case in West Germany after the war. This could mean getting rid of planning rules which hinder the transformation of the high street, occupational rules which reduce labour market flexibility, and a host of other employment obligations and prohibitions which reduce job opportunities. There could also be a fundamental rethink of planned increases in the National Living Wage. One way of rebuilding a prosperous economy that benefits everybody, especially those ‘left behind’, is to restore full employment, not to price workers out of a job or disincentivise them from seeking work. Higher taxes on individuals and corporations could slow the recovery. The fiscal costs of the crisis at least could be manageable without the need for tax increases, or ‘Austerity 2.0’. Government borrowing could shrink again as the economy recovers and the emergency fiscal measures are wound down. In the meantime, debt will be higher, but the increase should be readily financeable at low interest rates and there is no pressing need to pay it back. However, the sharp deterioration in the public finances may weaken the argument for even more fiscal stimulus. There could be a case for bringing forward some infrastructure spending, as long as the projects are worthwhile in their own right, and for increasing investment in skills training. But the focus could be on measures that help the supply side, including targeted tax cuts and deregulation, rather than ‘creating jobs’. The gradual easing of the lockdown and the return of consumer and business confidence could be sufficient to kick-start the economy. The Coronavirus Job Retention Scheme (CJRS) has played a valuable role in protecting jobs and incomes in the short run. But it is expensive and distortionary, and there are dangers in keeping defunct businesses on life support. Instead, they could be allowed to fail, freeing up resources for more productive uses. Large across-the-board increases in public sector pay and in welfare benefits may be inadvisable. In particular, a permanent Universal Basic Income could be poorly targeted and disproportionately expensive. Within the financial markets, additional regulation of ‘short sellers’ could prove counterproductive, as could imposing any further conditions on emergency support for companies, such as new environmental obligations or restrictions on dividends.
Finally, a lurch towards protectionism is possible. It is
true that globalisation – or, more accurately, global
travel – has helped to spread Covid-19. But cross-border supply
chains have held up relatively well, ensuring stable supplies of
food, business inputs and consumer goods. It could be highly
damaging to jeopardise the benefits of trade and
international travel just in case this might help to reduce the
costs of a future pandemic. Julian Jessop, IEA Economics Fellow and co-author of Rebooting Britain, says:
“The state has had to step
in to protect businesses and jobs while the
economy has been shut down, but now the government should prepare
to step aside and let markets work normally
again.” Professor Len Shackleton, IEA Editorial and Research Fellow and co-author of Rebooting Britain, says:
“Understandable concern over job losses should not lead
us into further ill-considered interventions in
the labour market. We need to make it easier and
cheaper for businesses to take on workers in productive
roles.” |